As we have already seen (in the introduction), Global trade has increased very substantially since WWII. This demonstrates the increasing economic integration between countries, driven by:
Post war reconstruction (Bretton Woods Agreement,1944, and the GATT,
1947, aimed at both preventing the disaster of the Great Depression,
and associated descent into protectionism, and avoiding further armed
conflict. The WTO site (GATT link) has a potted history of the
multilateral trade negotiations. The Brookings Institute
(undated) provides a "Principled history of the GATT & WTO" (21p), which is the opening chapter of a book on the WTO and developing countries.
Technology - especially the development of the container, and
more recently the spread of air freight, global communications, the
internet and the web.
(source: Economist: "In
a set of 22 industrialised countries containerisation explains a 320%
rise in bilateral trade over the first five years after adoption and
790% over 20 years. By comparison, a bilateral free-trade agreement
raises trade by 45% over 20 years and GATT membership adds 285%."
- Most Favoured Nation (MFN)(A.1)
(the principle of not
discriminating between one’s trading partners - the rules and
barriers applied to your country's 'most favoured nation' should be
applied to everyone else too). However, as Brookings (op.cit) notes:
the GATT/WTO does permit members to sign preferential trade agreements
(PTAs) between one another and thus offer lower-than-MFN tariff rates
to preferred partners provided that this covers “substantially all
trade.” Furthermore, the GATT/WTO also encourages members to
offer lower-than MFN tariff rates to developing country exporters
through the Generalized System of Preferences (GSP).” (p 17). - e.g.
the EU's "everything but arms" agreements
-National Treatment(A.3)
(The principle of giving others the
same treatment as one’s own nationals. GATT Article 3 requires that
imports be treated no less favourably than the same or similar
domestically-produced goods once they have passed customs. GATS Article
17 and TRIPS Article 3 also deal with national treatment for services
and intellectual property protection. Again, as Brookings (op cit)
notes: "“Evidence that the coverage of the national treatment principle
is broad and powerful is that it is the core issue in a large number of
the formal WTO disputes. In fact, in almost any dispute in which a WTO
member is alleged to have differentiated unfairly between domestic and
foreign-produced goods—whether it be because of a discriminatory tax
code, an explicit or implicit subsidy, or a regulatory barrier
motivated by concerns over environmental or consumer safety—the heart
of the issue is the applicability of and the potential limits to the
national treatment principle.” (p18)
- Tariffication & Binding
- Prohibition of Quotas
- Prohibition of Dumping & Export Subsidies
- Safeguards for national interests.
VanGrasstek, 2013, The History and Future of the WTO, WTO Geneva,
(625 pages of very detailed documentation and analysis) provides an
intersting and illuminating chart of the influence and dependence on
international merchandise trade (p. 31).
VanGrasstek's commentary on this chart is as follows (p31): "The data on trade dependence show that Germany
is, in addition to being the largest trader in the group and the
third-largest in the world, also the median country in the trading
system: at 76.4 per cent, its trade dependence is exactly equal to that of the global average.
As a general rule, the other large EU member states tend to be less
trade-dependent than Germany, as in the case of France, Italy and the
United Kingdom, while smaller members such as Belgium, the Czech
Republic, the Netherlands and the Slovak Republic are among the most
trade-dependent countries in the world. With trade having been the
original area of competence for the EU machinery, and having played
such a central role in the bloc’s existence, it is not surprising that
the European Union places a higher priority on this area of public
policy than the other large players do. The differing interests of EU
member states nonetheless make for a sometimes unstable negotiating
stance, not least on divisive and sensitive issues such as agriculture,
and it is the larger and less trade-dependent members, such as France,
that are more prone to apply the brakes even when smaller, more
trade-dependent members would prefer to step on the accelerator.
Compared with their EU counterparts, US policy-makers place a lower priority on this subject. The United States
is one of a handful of countries that are more important to the trading
system than the trading system is to them. Whereas this country
accounted for 10.2 per cent of global merchandise trade in 2011 (the highest of all), US trade in goods was the equivalent of just 24.8 per cent of the domestic economy (the third-lowest of all).
The relative share of trade vis-à-vis the domestic economy was about
three times greater in the average country than in the United States,
and for many of them it exceeded 100 per cent. The situation of Japan is similar to that of the United States.
Whereas this country was the fourth-largest trader in 2011, controlling
4.6 per cent of the total, trade was the equivalent of just 28.6 per
cent of the Japanese economy. Some
of the more prominent emerging and transitional economies share that
same characteristic of being more important to the trading system than
the trading system is to them. Consider Brazil, China, India, the
Russian Federation and South Africa. These five
countries collectively controlled 16.3 per cent of global merchandise
trade in 2011, and individually ranged from 0.6 per cent (South Africa)
to 9.9 per cent (China), but for each of these countries the value of
total trade in goods (imports plus exports) in 2011 was equivalent to a
smaller share of GDP than the global average of 76.4 per cent. That point is especially notable in the case of Brazil.
It was in fact the least trade-dependent country in the world in 2011,
with merchandise trade being equivalent to just 19.9 per cent of its GDP.
Trade dependence was also below the 76.4 per cent global average in
India (40.5 per cent), the Russian Federation (45.5 per cent), China
(49.8 per cent) and South Africa (53.5 per cent). To be sure, not all
emerging economies meet this description: Malaysia, for example, is
among the most trade-dependent of all economies (148.8 per cent). On
average, however, the largest emerging economies are, together with the
United States and Japan, among the least trade-dependent."
The implications are that the most influential countries (for global
trade) are now the least dependent on trade, which makes further
multilateral trade agreements under the WTO much more difficult (even
without the US adopting a more independent and potentially
protectionist stance) - witness the slow to zero progress with the
'current' Doha round of WTO negotiations.
Have the GATT/WTO rounds of agreements promoted/encouraged moreTrade? Arvind Subramanian and Shang-Jin Wei (2003): "The WTO Promotes Trade , Strongly But Unevenly",
IMF Working Paper, conclude that - Yes, it has - "the GATT/WTO has had
a powerful and positive impact on trade. The impact has, however, been
uneven. GATT/WTO membership for industrial countries has been
associated with a large increase in trade estimated at about 40 percent
of world trade. The same has not been true for developing country
members, although those that joined after the Uruguay Round have
benefited from increased trade. Similarly, there has been an asymmetric
impact between sectors, with WTO membership associated with
substantially greater trade in sectors where barriers are low. These
results are consistent with the history and design of the institution,
which presided over significant trade liberalization by the industrial
countries except in sectors such as food and clothing; largely exempted
developing countries from the obligations to liberalize under the
principle of special and differential treatment; but attempted to
redress the latter by imposing greater obligations on developing
country members that joined since the Uruguay Round."
The WTO's World Trade Report, 2011, Chapter 3, documents the historical background and current trends in preferential trade agreements. Some key facts and findings - a huge number of PTAs, but, perhaps surprisingly, covering only a fraction of total world merchandise trade.
• Almost 300 preferential trade agreements (notified and not notified) were in force in 2010.
• 13 is the average number of PTAs that a WTO member is party to.
• Only 16 per cent of global merchandise trade receives preferential treatment.
• Less than 2 per cent of world trade is eligible for preference margins above 10 percentage points.
“Creation of the GATT did not
diminish the attraction of bilateral or regional approaches to
international trade relations. On the contrary, the push for new
regional agreements, especially in Europe, re-emerged less than five
years after the GATT was launched, ushering in a long period of
creative tension between regionalism and multilateralism, and paving
the way for dramatic advances in both approaches. If the
mid-nineteenth century marked the first major phase of regionalism, the
last 60 years have witnessed three additional phases or “waves”. Each
has been driven, at least in part, by a perceived need among groups of
countries to go “further and faster” than the broader GATT system in
order to manage “deeper” trade integration (Carpenter, 2009). Although
the widening and deepening of the European Union has been at the centre
of each successive wave of regionalism, North America and now Asia have
also joined the race. At the same time, each wave has tended to
coincide with – or be immediately followed by – significant advances in
GATT negotiations, leading some to argue that there is a process of
competitive liberalization, or “domino effect”, not just among the
various regional agreements, but more fundamentally between regionalism
and multilateralism.” (p. 51/2) 1st wave: 1950s and 60s ECSC
(’51)-> EEC (’57) (&EFTA, for the others) + Africa, Caribbean,
Central and S. America – though most collapsed by end of ‘70s.
"The launch of the Dillon Round of trade negotiations in 1960 was
prompted in part because the adoption of the EEC's common external
tariff required the renegotiation of certain members' bound tariff
rates (i.e. the upper limit for members' tariff rates) – a process
which encouraged these members to seek reciprocal tariff reductions
from trade partners in a broader multilateral context. Likewise, the
more ambitious Kennedy Round between 1964 and 1967 coincided with
negotiations to expand the EEC to include Britain, Ireland, Denmark,
Greece and Norway (which did not join)
– and was motivated in part by US concerns about being excluded from an
ever-broader and more unified European market (Anderson and Blackhurst,
1993). Thus, GATT tariff
cutting and membership enlargement moved in tandem with the widening
and deepening of Europe's integration project, as well as with other
regional initiatives. (p.52) 2nd wave: (mid’80s – ‘90s) –
again EU led –1st enlargement, 2nd Iberian expansion (’86)->
EEC->EU (Mastricht) & single market ’93, Austria, Finland and
Sweden accession ’95, Eastern preparation and expansion ’04, and
Romania Bulgaria ‘07, and subsequently
by the US: "Having eschewed regionalism in favour of multilateralism
for almost 40 years, the United States suddenly shifted strategies, embarking on an ambitious programme of bilateral negotiations that included, first, a free trade agreement with Israel in 1985, and then, more dramatically, the Canada-US Free Trade Agreement in 1988, later trilateralized to include Mexico in NAFTA in the early 1990s (Anderson and Blackhurst, 1993). Much
of the “new” trade policy agenda that the United States had been
seeking in the multilateral arena – such as investment, services trade,
intellectual property rights, and government procurement – was
incorporated first in these bilateral and regional talks, and then
taken up in the Uruguay Round negotiations." (p.
52) Latin America followed suit (Mercosur), as did some of Africa
(e.g. SADAC), and somewhat later, Asia as well. "After several failed
attempts, the Uruguay Round was launched in 1986, including for the first time a negotiating mandate on services, intellectual property and, to a more limited extent, investment. Despite
concerns about the GATT being eclipsed by regional deals – or because
of them – the Uruguay Round was successfully concluded in 1994, crowned
with the creation of the WTO, effectively taking some of the energy out of this second wave of regionalism." (p. 53) 3rd wave: " most recent “wave” of regionalism covers a much wider network of participants
– including bilateral, plurilateral and cross-regional initiatives –
and encompasses countries at different levels of economic development –
including “developed-developed”, “developing-developing”, and
“developed-developing” alliances. And although these new agreements,
like previous PTAs, also involve preferential tariff reductions, they
focus even more on WTO-plus type issues, such as services, capital
flows, standards, intellectual property, regulatory systems (many of
which are non-discriminatory) and commitments on labour and environment
issues." (p. 53)
Some Key Charts from this report: For an impressive interactive representation of the proliferation of PTAs, see the GED Project page.
However, there is another explanation for the growth in world trade, as
measured by these data on merchandise trade: global value chains
and 'distributed manufacture' - illustrated by the iPad 'value added' story. "iPads
are assembled in Chinese factories owned by Foxconn, a Taiwanese firm,
largely from parts produced outside China. According to a study by the
Personal Computing Industry Centre, each iPad sold in America adds
$275, the total production cost, to America's trade deficit with China,
yet the value of the actual work performed in China accounts for only
$10. Using these numbers, The Economist estimates that iPads
accounted for around $4 billion of America's reported trade deficit
with China in 2011; but if China's exports were measured on a
value-added basis, the deficit was only $150m."
Essentially, the development of these global integrated supply chains
can be seen as a logical development of the comparative
advantage/specialise and trade logic as communications systems improve,
as transport costs decline, and as trust in offshore partners increases
(as people learn by doing).
A footnote on the latest (and first) WTO agreement: The Trade Facilitation Agreement
(February, 2017) "which seeks to expedite the movement, release and
clearance of goods across borders, launches a new phase for trade
facilitation reforms all over the world and creates a significant boost
for commerce and the multilateral trading system as a whole. Full
implementation of the TFA is forecast to slash members' trade costs by
an average of 14.3 per cent, with developing countries having the most
to gain, according to a 2015 study carried out by WTO
economists." "Spread out over 12 articles, the TFA prescribes
many measures to improve transparency and predictability of trading
across borders and to create a less discriminatory business
environment. The TFA's
provisions include improvements to the availability and publication of
information about cross-border procedures and practices, improved
appeal rights for traders, reduced fees and formalities connected with
the import/export of goods, faster clearance procedures and enhanced
conditions for freedom of transit for goods. The Agreement also
contains measures for effective cooperation between customs and other
authorities on trade facilitation and customs compliance issues."
One illustration of economic disintegration is the collapse of the USSR in 1990: (see, Cleaver, p 16-18, and e.g., Harrison, University of Warwick, 2003, and Lin, The Brookings Institution, 2004.
FOR AN EXCELLENT REVIEW OF TRADE (Economic Integration) AND SOCIO-ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT, SEE LOVE
& LATTIMORE: International
Trade: Free, Fair and Open?, OECD, 2009.
2. FINANCIAL INTEGRATION
Cleaver (Ch 7) provides a sensible account of money, banking and
international finance. He explains the "global explosion of finance"
since the major financial deregulations of the '80s (especially in the
US and UK under Reagan and Thatcher respectively) as being caused by:
Trade and the need to both finance trade and recycle surpluses:
Cold war development of essentially unregulated 'EuroDollar' markets
through offshore banks operating outside domestic exchange and monetary
controls - operating wholesale (large transaction volumes) "large
turnovers, small margins and regulation avoidance -> commercial
success and strong competition to domestically based banks. The
collapse of the fixed exchange rate regime, and the oil price boom (and
associated trade surpluses and deficits) generated major opportunities
for international finance companies. Subsequently, the rapid growth in
Asia, especially China, largely on the basis of exports, further
generated trade imbalances and the need for offsetting capital account
financial flows.
Technology: - computing and communications -> virtual and virtually instantaneous trading.
Deregulation: -
once begun becomes progressive as banks and financial intermediaries
(such as insurance companies) press their governments to allow them to
compete effectively with less regulated foreign competitors ->
mergers and acquisitions to generate global banks and insurance
companies. See, e.g. Sherman, 2009, A Short History of Financial Deregulation in the US. (highlighted by your lecturer)
The consequences of these changes in the world's finance markets led to
an explosion of financial contracts and associated assests and
liabilities, as well as growth and global consolidation in the number
and inter-relationships between the financial 'intermediaries' and bank
activities, setting the scene for a succession of debt crises and credit crunches. What are these banks and financial intermediaries trying to do? (short answer - make money)The Finance Watch page
provides a basic account of financial markets (though beware - while FW
has the laudable aim of "making finance serve society", it can get
things wrong (e.g. excessive speculation on agricultural commodity
exchanges causing commodity price spikes, on which there is very
limited if any substantive evidence).
The Economist - history of financial crashes (below) - says: "finance does just two simple things. It can act as an economic time machine,
helping savers transport today’s surplus income into the future, or
giving borrowers access to future earnings now. It can also act as a safety net, insuring against floods, fires or illness.
By providing these two kinds of service, a well-tuned financial system
smooths away life’s sharpest ups and downs, making an uncertain world
more predictable. In addition, as investors seek out people and
companies with the best ideas, finance acts as an engine of growth."
facilitate trade -
providing for the exchange of money and credit, typically 'across the
exchanges (i.e. involving the exchange of one currency for another) -
the easier the better for trade, and thus for economic development;
match savings with investment (the
'capital market' function) - harnessing trading and other surpluses
with demands for loans (to finanance both physical and productive
investments, and consumption); as GDP grows, so, too, does the demand
for and supply of 'loanable funds' (savings and borrowings), see, e.g. Domestic credit provided by the financial sector as a %GDP, World Bank
preserve and enhance wealth (accumulated savings of clients, and manage pension funds), the demand for which also grows with GDP;
spread risk - insurance
is the classic example, but now massively expanded to include insurance
against adverse price and exchange rate movements.
How do they try to do it?
Borrowing (savings) v. Lending rate margins:
traditional bank earnings stream - competiton obliges these margins to
be as small as possible, given the transaction costs and necessary
returns to risk of default.
arbitrage: essentially,
buy cheap and sell dear - both for commodites and financial assets
(whose value depends on their future earnings and on interest rates),
so extending to borrow cheaply and lend expensively. Given sufficient
competition in the markets, this activity should result in an efficient market
hedging: offsetting opposing risks, as in the traditional commodity futures exchanges
which offset, or balance, the different risks of the buyers and sellers
of e.g. wheat. (note, especially, that commodity futures exchanges rely on speculators
(who only bet on one-way movements in prices) to maintain liquidity in
the market (frequency and ease of trading (exchanging) futures
contracts) which preserves their price formation and discovery
functions, and require traders to cover their margin(good faith deposits required from trader or investor entering into a long or short position on a futures contract.)
portfolio management:
Spreading risk through construction and management of diversified
portfolios of investments - balancing different risks and risk
exposures (and charging a fee for these services) -> to creation of
novel forms of 'derivatives' to spread risk
speculation: i.e. betting on future price movements -> also leads to the development of 'derivatives' and spread betting etc.
The Economist essay on the history of financial crashes
provides a sketch of how finance markets have been prone to booms and
busts since their inception. This history illustrates the fundamental
problem: Commercial Banks provide the lubricant (money) for the
modern economy to work, but they are prone to take on excessive
risk in the pursuit of private profit. Since runs on banks
(where all depositers demand their money back at the same time, when
there is simply not enough money to meet the demand) will lead to
economic depressions, governments are persuaded to underwrite the banks
and hence underwrite the risks. This creates a moral hazard
- people likely to take more risks if they are insured than if not - so
banks (insured by Governments) take more risks, especially if they are
regarded as 'too big to fail'. Furthermore, governments try to
keep interest rates as low as possible (other things equal), to
encourage investment, and subsidise banks. (Economist, April, 2014). The result isHyman Minsky's financial instabilityhypothesis (as in previous notes on stock markets), which describes three kinds of financing:
"The first, which he called hedge financing, is the safest: companies can repay debts with their earnings. They have limited borrowings and good profits.
The second, speculative financing,
is a little riskier: companies can cover their interest payments but
must roll over their principal. This works fine normally but not in
downturns.
The third, Ponzi financing, is the most dangerous. Earnings cover neither principal nor interest; firms are betting that their assets will appreciate. If not, they are in trouble.
Economies dominated by hedge
financing—those with strong cashflows and low debt levels—are stable.
When speculative and, especially, Ponzi financing become popular,
economies are vulnerable. If asset values fall, overstretched investors
must sell their positions. This further hits asset values, causing pain
for even more investors, and so on—a downward spiral now sometimes
called a “Minsky moment”. Investors would have done better to stick to
hedge financing. But over time, particularly when the economy is
healthy, debt is irresistible. When growth seems guaranteed, why not
borrow more? Banks add to the dynamic, lowering their standards the
longer booms last. If defaults are minimal, why not lend more? Mr
Minsky’s conclusion was unsettling: periods of stability breed
financial fragility." (Economist, ibid) The differential tax
treatment of capital gains (increase in the value of assets such as
stocks and shares) versus the treatment of dividends (the annual yields
from these stocks) can also affect stock market bubbles - such as the dot.com bubble 1997-2003.
The 2008 Credit Crunch and the Financial Crisis.
Cleaver, ch. 9 provides the background, including synopses of previous
debt and financial crises and lessons learned (or not).Good accounts of
the 2008 crisis are the Economist (2013) and Bill Robinson, Citywire Money, Sept, 2008.
The Economist says "it is clear the crisis had multiple causes (the Congressional Research Service, Mark Jickling, April 2010, records 26 plausible reasons, and brief counter-arguments)
The most obvious is the financiers themselves—especially
the irrationally exuberant Anglo-Saxon sort, who claimed to have found
a way to banish risk when in fact they had simply lost track of it:
(irresponsible mortgage lending (encouraged by government), sub-prime
mortgages repackaged in special investment vehicles (SIVs), otherwise
known as Collaterised Debt Obligations (CDOs), and sold on as assets
and backed up with Credit Default Swaps (CDSs) as supposed insurance on
the mortgage bonds, - see Dan Wang's explanation): Dominoes: The banks (including Lehman
Brothers, Merrill Lynch, and J.P. Morgan) and the insurance companies
(including AIG), all either owned CDOs or sold credit default swaps.
They found that their CDOs had failed, and were on the hook for
billions of losses because they bet wrong. Dozens of banks failed, the most
high-profile of which are Lehman Brothers and Bear Sterns. AIG declared
bankruptcy. Merrill Lynch was sold to Bank of America. People started
to panic, and credit markets seized up. Businesses struggled to keep
their loans and get new ones. It was at this time that Congress
passed TARP, the Troubled Asset Relief Program, a $700 billion bailout
of the big banks and the insurance companies. Citigroup, for example,
received $45 billion; AIG received $40 billion; J.P. Morgan and Wells
Fargo both received $25 billion; Goldman Sachs received $10 billion;
and so on. Meanwhile, the hedge funds that saw the crisis coming made
billions.
Central bankers and other regulators
also bear blame, for it was they who tolerated this folly (perhaps,
especially, the Credit Rating Agencies (paid for by Finance companies),
who incorrectly rated risky mortgage bonds as AAA etc., while Central
Banks perhaps kept interest rates too low).
The macroeconomic backdrop was important, too. The “Great Moderation”—years of low inflation and stable growth—fostered complacency and risk-taking, and was associated with US Government encouragement of house ownership, and relaxed mortgage rules.
A “savings glut” in Asia pushed down global interest rates.
(Low interest rates created an incentive for banks, hedge funds and
other investors to hunt for riskier assets that offered higher returns.
They also made it profitable for such outfits to borrow and use the
extra cash to amplify (leverage) their investments, on the assumption
that the returns would exceed the cost of borrowing. The low volatility
of the Great Moderation increased the temptation to “leverage” in this
way. If short-term interest rates are low but unstable, investors will
hesitate before leveraging their bets. But if rates appear stable,
investors will take the risk of borrowing in the money markets to buy
longer-dated, higher-yielding securities - an architypical Minsky
progression).
Some research also implicates European banks, which borrowed greedily in American money markets before the crisis and used the funds to buy dodgy securities.
All these factors came together to foster a surge of debt in what seemed to have become a less risky world."
Bill Robinson ascribes the underlying cause to "a global surplus of savings.
The most famous symptom is China’s large current account surplus.This
represents the net savings of the Chinese nation, which has been
consistently used to buy US government bonds. The oil exporting
countries run similar surpluses, which have grown as the oil price has
risen, and are also large purchasers of bonds. The resulting strong
demand for bonds has driven up their price and driven down real yields
to extraordinarily low levels. The resulting availability of cheap credit fuelled the long boom since 2000 and had a particularly strong impact on the housing market."
Though, as the Economist (op.cit) notes: "Hyun Song Shin, an economist
at Princeton University, has focused on the European role in fomenting
the crisis. The glut that caused America’s loose credit conditions
before the crisis, he argues, was in global banking rather than in world savings."
The immediate consequences of the Credit crunch - commercial banks
calling in loans and unwilling to lend because of uncertainty about
their assets - was an underwriting of the banks and insurance companies
(Troubled Asset Relief Programme (TARP), and the effective transfer of private sector borrowing to the
public sector. Subsequent fiscal stimulus added to the public sector
deficits - Treasury Borrowing - to offset an econonomic depression. Source: Understanding the Flow of Funds Systemand the Financial Crisis of 2008, David Nawrocki and Fred Viole, Dec. 2012.
The Euro Crisis. Again, Cleaver, ch 9, provides a synopsis, while the European Commission also provides a brief account, and the New York Times has a graphical illustration of the continental and global interactions. Economics Help also has a readable explanation, as does Der Spiegel. The Economist, Nov. 2015, comments: " that the euro-area crisis was not a sovereign-debt crisis.
If it had been, one would have expected Belgium and Italy, which
entered the crisis with extraordinarily high debts, to have landed in
serious trouble. As it turned out, they made it through without troika
programmes, while Ireland and Spain, which entered the crisis with low
levels of sovereign debt, needed bail-outs. The problem, instead, was
one of massive
capital flows across borders, which encouraged high levels of private
borrowing in the economies that eventually got into trouble. When the global financial crisis generated a reversal in those flows, private borrowers and banks got into big trouble. That
trouble translated into serious economic downturns and bank failures,
both of which led to explosive growth in sovereign debt burdens. Exploding sovereign debt was the symptom rather than the cause of the crisis." One graph illustrates the eventual nature of the crisis.
The BBC provides a timeline., and charts (GDP growth, unemployment, public (government) debt and budget deficits) for EU countries from 1999-2014 (complete with the Masstricht Treaty limits on debts and deficits as % of GDP (now under the Stability & Growth Pact for the Eurozone)
As widely expected, and as simple theory suggests, the formation of the Euro meant a convergence of Eurozone interest rates
(here measured as the implict rate from the price of 10 year Government
bonds. Notice, Greece was not admited to the Euro immediately,
and even when allowed to join was clearly in breach of the Maastricht
Treaty limits on both budget defits and public (government) debt as
proportions of GDP (see BBC charts), but then so too were several
other members of the Euro.
However, it took the banking
crisis triggered by the credit crunch in late 2008 to fully expose the
economic nonsense of a single interest rate throughout the Eurozone. The credit crunch collapsed
property prices, especially in Ireland and Spain, and left all European
banks exposed to the huge uncertainty about what their assets were
actually worth, and about the extent of their liabilities. To prevent a
complete collaps of the banking system, virtually all member
governments had to step in to underwrite their banks exposure, and
hence assume their debts. As in the US (above), public (government)
deficits and debts increased as a consequence (again, see BBC charts).
The fiction of a single interest rate for the Euro members was now
brutally exposed. Would and could the Euro survive? If not, what
would the finances of member countries (especially the PIGS (Portugal,
Ireland, Greece and Spain)) look like? The
finance markets responded as shown in the graph above, immediately
reducing the price (and hence raising the implicit interest rate) on
these countries public debt (as represented in the value of their
government bonds).
Greece, especially, was seen as the most likely country to leave (or be
evicted from) the Euro, because its domestic economy was the most
obviously unsustainable (large external (BoP) deficit, substantial
government debt and large budget deficits - the latter two heavily
disguised with the help of international finance companies to partially
conceal their full extent). Without leaving the Euro, and hence denied the possibility of a substantial devaluation of the Greek currency, what options are there to relieve the Greek (and other PIGS) problems?
Debt relief
(writing off the public debts - meaning that the creditors, widely
dispersed throughout the global financial system, would loose, and
these (and other) countries would not be penalised for their excesses -
creating a substantial moral hazard - encouraging othe countries within
the Eurozone to also behave profligately, especially in times of low
interest rates);
Stronger growth
to provide the income streams to allow debts and deficits to be reduced
(which means both fiscal and monetary policy to expand the economies);
Structural and policy reform
to improve the performance of the domestic economy - necessary in any
event in Greece, and also elsewhere, to reform tax policy to capture
more of the economic activity, and reform government spending to
eliminate unproductive and extravagent spending (overblown public
services etc.);
Fiscal Austerity - to reduce government spending - not exactly consistent with stronger growth.
The "Troika"
comprising the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the European
Commission and the European Central Bank, although finding it difficult
to agree, did provide bailout assistance to Greece
- arranging a 'haircut' on some public debt, providing additional
monetary reserves to finance internal reforms, on heavy conditions
about the nature and extent of these internal reforms. These
succesive bailouts are still going on, and mirror to a large extent
what the international community had already done to developing
countries with large debts in the '90s. The ECB has also embarked on 'quantitative easing' (against some considerable opposition, especially from Germany (see Martin Wolf, FT, May 2016),
buying Eurobonds, and hence driving their prices up and reducing the
interest rate, while injecting additional money into the banking
sector, which is supposed to encourage bank lending and hence reflate
the economy - though mostly through the reflation of housing and
property markets (helping Ireland, especially).
However, at least in the 'short term', internal reforms are difficult
and anyway take time to happen. Meanwhile, growth is not happening -
the very reverse (again, see BBC graphs above). Fiscal austerity is
making the situation worse, not better - we need more growth throughout
the EU and Eurozone. While the Irish have managed to regenerate
economic growth, and hence eased their difficulties, the other
vulnerable and exposed countries have not. The key problem facing the Euro
is that it is inherently unbalanced, and lacks any fiscal means of
assisting the rebalancing of the Erozone economies (no large scale
transfers of public funds between the prosperous and lagging regions -
the EU budget is fixed by treaty to be no more than 1.4% of GDP - tiny
in comparision with other national/single currency areas such as the UK
or the US).
In addition, the reluctance of Germany (especially) to recycle its
substantial trade surplus to other countries with large deficits, and
its additional reluctance to countenace relaxation of fiscal austerity
(reflecting its history of the problems of fiscal excess financed by
monetary expansion) makes the problem even more difficult.
On the other hand, preservation of the Euro (and thus the Eurozone) is
a political imperative, especially in Germany, which has benefited
substantially from being in the Euro and part of a wider and larger
economic entity. Its exchange rate has been the Euro exchange rate,
rather than the much stronger D'mark (at least after recovery from the economic
trauma of German unification at parity), hence benefiting its exports
and making imports cheaper than otherwise. Without full fiscal union, and hence full political union,
the Euro will always be vulnerable to disintegration - a realisation which
makes it even more vulnerable, since political union to, effectively, a
European superstate, is very far from the ambitions and aspirations of
many, if not most, of its citizens.
From its inception, the Euro has been a bold political experiment -
intended to foster trade, economic activity and convergence and bolster
European unity in the face of very substantial, if not insurmountable
economic reality. It remains a political aspiration rather than an
economic foundation (see Jo Stiglitz, August, 2016,
the Problem with Europe is the Euro). If Germany (or France or Italy)
had been obliged to hold a public referendum prior to joining the Euro,
it would probably never have happened. If the UK government has decided
that joing the Euro was a good idea, then it would almost certainly
have been obliged to hold a referendum to ratify its decision, and
would again almost certainly have lost. Perhaps the only way the
British public might have been persuaded that joining the Euro was a
sensible thing to do woujld have been to demand that the EU adopt a
common language as well as a common currency, and that it should be
called the pound, and not the Euro. Even then ....
3. Why did no one see this coming? What went wrong?
Paul Krugman (NY Times, Sept, 2009) explains How Economists got it so wrong: (quotes below are from this article)
i) Macro-economists were complacent:
they had got over their 1960s quarrels about whether monetary or fiscal
policies were more important (stable monetary policies, targeting
inflation were all that was needed, re-inforced by the experience with
stagflation in the 1970s); fiscal fine-tuning (counter-cyclical)
policy was counter-productive; leading to a complacency largely born
out by the 'great moderation' - a sustained period of growth, low(ish)
unemployment, and low inflation. "Between 1985 and 2007 a false peace settled over the field of macroeconomics." "The
Fed (US central bank) dealt with the recession that began in 1990 by
driving short-term interest rates from 9 percent down to 3 percent. It
dealt with the recession that began in 2001 by driving rates from 6.5
percent to 1 percent. And it tried to deal with the current recession
by driving rates down from 5.25 percent to zero."
ii) with a pervasive belief that finance markets are (always) efficient - the efficient market hypothesis, (Lo, 2008) and closely related 'capital assets pricing model' (CAPM). "Finance
economists rarely asked the seemingly obvious (though not easily
answered) question of whether asset prices made sense given real-world
fundamentals like earnings. Instead, they asked only whether asset
prices made sense given other asset prices."
Krugman argues: "So here’s what I
think economists have to do. First, they have to face up to the
inconvenient reality that financial markets fall far short of
perfection, that they are subject to extraordinary delusions and the
madness of crowds. Second, they have to admit — and this will be very
hard for the people who giggled and whispered over Keynes — that
Keynesian economics remains the best framework we have for making sense
of recessions and depressions. Third, they’ll have to do their best to
incorporate the realities of finance into macroeconomics."
How does this fit with the 'basic principles' (DRH's 'rationalisation')
Capital 'markets' are conceptually different from Finance markets, and largely disconnected in models of the macroeconomy.
The basic macroeconomic models (from the CFoI and the notion of an
aggregate supply function or aggregate production function), capital markets are those which mediate between the flows of savings (earnings not spent on current consumption) and flows of investment
(additions to the productive capacity of the economy (new plant,
equipment, infrastructure, labour and management skills etc.).
Finance markets, on the other hand, are largely concerned with the
valuations and exchanges of stocks of both paper and physical assets,
since the total stock of physical (and human) capital assets does not
change at all quickly, and can be considered more or less fixed in the
short term.
Neither of these markets establish 'the rate of interest' for the economy - this is established in the Money market, through the actions of the Central Bank (the Federal Reserve in the US, the BoE in the UK and the ECB for the Euro area).
Typically, the macroeconomic models used by treasuries, finance ministries and departments and central banks do not include any aspects of the finance markets
- they focus on the interaction between monetary policy (the money
market) and the real economy as the circular flow of income (aggregate
demand), and some notion of supply capacity. This ignorance of the
finance markets is justified by the belief that these markets are
'efficient' - that they accurately determine the prices of assets and
associated relative risks, and hence the constellation of interest
rates accounting for the differences in risk, and hence mediate
appropriately between the money market and the capital markets.
But the efficient market hypothesis(EMH)
is NOT about the social efficiency of the finance markets - whether or
not they actually lead to more secure and stable savings
opportunities, or more intelligent and productive investments for
our collective futures. It is ONLY about whether or not finance markets
'correctly' price stocks of capital (and all their derivatives). Recent
history strongly suggests that they don't, at least not reliably. As
Lo, 2008, (the link above) says, the EMH is, essentially: “individual
investors form expectations rationally, markets aggregate information
efficiently, and equilibrium prices incorporate all available
information instantaneously.” However, stock markets cannot be perfect in this sense, as Grossman and Stiglitz, 1980 argue. “Because
information is costly, prices cannot perfectly reflect the information
which is available, since if it did, those who spent resources to
obtain it would receive no compensation (and hence would be unable to
survive and persist). There is a fundamental conflict between the
efficiency with which markets spread information and the incentives to
acquire information" (p405). Grossman, S. and
Stiglitz, J. 1980. “On the impossibility of informationally efficient
markets”, American Economic Review 70, 393–408
As Lo (op cit.) observes, in making the case for an evolutionary approach to finance market behaviour (the adaptive markets hypothesis): “The
extraordinary degree of competitiveness of global financial markets and
the outsize rewards that accrue to the ‘fittest’ traders suggest that
Darwinian selection – ‘survival of the richest’, to be precise – is at
work in determining the typical profile of the successful trader. After
all, unsuccessful traders are eventually eliminated from the population
after suffering a certain level of losses.”Instead
of doing what the markets for goods and services do, which is to ensure
the survival of the fittest, finance markets essentially ensure the
survival of the fattest.
Unfortunaely, but predictably (according to Minsky's Financial Instability Hypothesis),
a boom and crash cycle is practically inevitable. Central are
then obliged to underwrite commerical banks, since not doing so could
only make matters worse - hence regulation of the finance markets to
ensure that they remain prudent is essential. Deregulation
of the finance markets in the 1980s and 90s led, eventually, to the
Credit Crunch and subsequent Sovereign Debt crises.