ACE 2006: Capital, Asset & Finance
Markets
Given that markets for goods and services operate largely as does
competition and natural selection in natural evolution - except that in
socio-economic evolution, the criteria for social and economic
selection and persistence are internal
and endogenous rather than god-given (given outside
determinants) as the laws of bio-physics (external and exogenous) - how
do capital and finance markets fit the picture? What are the
natural counterparts or analogues of capital?
The short answer is that there are
none - the natural world does NOT 'own' or accumulate assets (aside
from a bit of nut hoarding by squirrels etc., and some limited boundary
protection activity). Capital, capitalism and finance markets are
socially constructed human inventions - and, as a consequence, need to
be 'governed' somehow - the socio-economic (and hence political) rules
and codes for persistence and selection are necessarily endogenous and
internal. Goods and services markets embody the internal
selection criteria through consumers - the consumer is (ultimately)
sovereign, and determines who succeeds and who doesn't, and hence
continually re-generates the incomes which drive consumption through
the circular flow of income. What about capital and finance
markets? Who (or what) drives, sanctions and legitimises these
markets?
First,
how did they evolve? Goods and services 'markets' first
emerged as barter - I will give you food if you give me shelter - which
allows specialistation and (at least implicitly) trade. But the
scope of this is pretty limited. Barter became seriously
lubricated and dramatically extended with the invention of money - a commonly accepted and trusted medium of exchange which could
'stand in for' the equivalent amount of any good or service (and hence
allowed for and required the articulation of a price for each good and service as
the amount of the common numeraire
- money - which a unit of the good or service commanded). ->
whatever is used as money, it had better be: convenient and easy to
use, carry, store (and so be durable/hard-wearing) etc.;
difficult/impossible to counterfeit; and so be reliable - if
anyone/everyone can 'print' their own, they will and the 'money' will
quickly become useless - the rules
(properties of money, in this case) have to be
made by people and their governers and stuck to for socio-evolution to
be sustainable. Money is a fundamental and archetypical
exhibition of the endogeneity of the selection criteria in
socio-economic
evolution: if we cease to believe in it, it ceases to work; if we
worship it, we get what we deserve.
Once trade and exchange develop through the lubricant of
a reliable money, so promisory notes
and bills of exchange become commonplace (identifying
transactions (exchanges of ownership) of particular commodities or
services). Ownership of these bills and notes become pretty well
as good as the ownership of the goods, commodities and services.
They are almost as good as money, and indeed discount houses quickly establish
as businesses which will exchange these bills and promisory notes for
money (bank notes and coin). Meanwhile, banks (storehouses and safekeepers of
assets) have long been around - exploiting economies of scale and of
specialist knowledge, reputation, equipment, buildings, and
skills. Discount houses can rather quickly become banks for money
- the founders of most of British banking grew from discount houses,
while the founders of Italian banks grew from the storage of the
valuables of pilgrims. Banks rather quickly learn that depositors
seldom all return and require their money or assets back all at once,
so banks put their customers' stores of wealth to use by lending it out
to others. They can 'lever' more lending by encouraging depositors to
guarantee that they will not require repayment (reimbursment) within a
given period of time by offering interest
on the deposits (paid for by the interest the banks charge on their
loans to debtors). Banks rely on the trust of their depositors
that their money (wealth) is safe with the bank - if, for any reason,
depositors become nervous that their money might not be safe, they will
rush to get it back before it is too late - a run on the bank, which
can quickly bankrupt the bank, and 'destroying' the wealth of the
depositors. Hence, bankers need to be fundamentally prudent - taking
care to ensure that their debtors can and do at least pay the interest
on their loans, and, if not, actually have some assets (collateral)
which will serve to discharge the loan - forcing the threat of
bankruptcy back up the chain to the banks' debtors (those who have bank
loans). Nevertheless, the attraction of banking as an easy way to
make money encourages greed and lack of prudence - the results of which
can give banking as a whole a bad name. So, commercial banks become
'regulated' - licenced and guaranteed by the central authorities (the
central (national) bank - the Bank of England), which insures banks
against runs (lack of liquidity) by providing reserve funds, in return
for undertakings of the commercial banks to behave prudently and
maintain their own capital reserves at a reasonable level.
Citizens need to store their wealth (save) for their old age (pensions)
and against unforseen circumstances (insurance) - precuationary saving is what most
of us do most of the time. We require that our options for doing so are
secure (wealth will not lose its value, ideally, increase in value).
Pension funds and insurance companies, both mutual (cooperative) and
commercial (for 'profit' - as a measn of earning a living) necessarily
emerge to provide these services. All of these organisations
(banks, pension funds and insurance companies) are responsible (or not)
for looking after peoples' and businesses') savings, and compete to do
so most effectively so as to attract savings (albeit that the
information required by the savings customer (creditor) is especially
difficult to identify and interpret, meaning that the competition for
storage and security of savings is likely to be imperfect at best).
On the other side of these financial markets are the borrowers
(debtors) who want to borrow against either collateral or future
earning prospects to make real investments (in machinery, plant,
equipment, new buildings, human skills etc) in productive capital (as physical, productive
assets). In addition to private individuals and companies, governments
also need to borrow money to bridge the difference between tax (and
other government revenues) and expenditures (including those on
physical, human and social capital - 'genuine' investment) - and issue bonds (government i.o.u) to do so,
selling these gilt edged securities
to banks etc. in return for the loan, and paying fixed rates of return
on the face value of the bond in return). Similarly, corporate
business discovers the advantages of the limited liability company, and
issue shares in the company's
total value (it's stock) - which grants shares in the company’s profits
(and losses) to a number of (perhaps distant and rather disconnected)
people, in order to access a greater volume of investment (speculative)
finance necessary to operate the business. Bonds and shares
become traded in the stock and finance markets. But these stock markets are
fundamentally different from those we have been dealing with for goods
and services (which are markets for flows of production and
consumption).
In effect, we have three conceptually seperate but highly inter-related
finance and asset markets: 1; the market for money itself;
2 the markets in which savings (loanable funds) are matched with real
(physical and human capital) investment opportunities; 3 stock markets,
which simply exchange the ownership of claims on real economic activity.
1. The Market for Money (Money market)
Money is used both as a medium of exchange for transactions (active
bank
balances) and also as a store of wealth (idle bank balances).
Demand
for and Supply of Money: The price of money is
the interest
rate (what it costs to get more of it!)
- Demand for money (current account bank balances) depends on:
- Income (especially for transactions or active balances)
- Price (the interest rate) especially for idle balances - the
higher the
interest rate, the greater the opportunity cost of holding wealth as
money
rather than as financial or physical assets.
- Money Supply is controlled by the Monetary Authority - the Bank
of
England
(BoE).
- Monetary Policy is decided by the Monetary Policy Committe of the
BoE,
with the objectve of controlling inflation
- either through controlling the Supply of Money directly (which
proves
to
be rather difficult)
- or by setting the base lending (interest) rate of the Bank of
England
to
the commercial banking system - the current system of Monetary policy.
(Setting the interest rate at a new level above r* will automatically
result
in a contraction of the supply of money to match the reduced demand -
since
the BoE, through its function as lender of last resort, implicitly sets
the
supply of money to match its ruling interest rate)
2. Capital Markets: Balance between Savings
and Investment (in new
plant
and equipment etc.)
The rate of interest also influences Savings and Investment - the
balance
in the capital market for loanable (investment)
funds
Notice:
If the interest rate (set in the money market) results in I > S,
then there
will be a tendency for the level of National Income (Y) to grow -
increasing
savings (shifting this ceteris paribusSavings supply curve
shifts
to the right as incomes increase) to match the additional
investment.
However, increasing Y might also increase Imports and Taxes - so that
the
imbalance between savings and investment might persist - offset by
imbalances
between G and T, and between IM and X. - from the Circular
Flow of
Income and the necessary balance of funds.
3. Financial and Asset Markets - who owns what
bits of existing
capital.
The Stock Market: where already existing shares are swapped
between
people who want more (buyers) and people who want to hold fewer shares
(the sellers). The total stock of shares is pretty well fixed (aside
from
occasional new issues).
The land market:
The total stock of land is Qf. Whatever the price, this
total
stock cannot be changed (aside from minor changes like draining lakes
etc.)
The sellers are signalling a negative demand for the thing
(land
in this case) - the offer curve (Oc) - the higher the price, the
greater the quantity we might expect present owners to be willing to
sell.
By the same token, all present owners who are
not selling are exhibiting
a positive demand for their stock given present prices. This
positve
demand is labelled the reservation demand (RD) in the
above
figure, which is the mirror image of the offer curve (Oc). What
is not being offered for sale by present owners is being retained (held
onto) - that is, it is being demanded.
The excess demand curve (XD) shows how much more
land present owners and non owners want to own at each price -
more
is demanded over and above present holdings of land as the
price
falls.
The horizontal sum of the reservation demand (RD) and
the excess demand (XD) is the total demand (TD)
for
land, or stock. It is the intersection of this total demand (TD)with
the fixed supply (Sf) which determines the market price for land
(Pe).
The trades we observe in a stock market are those between people who
no longer want to own the stock, for whatever reason, shown by the
offer
curve (Oc) and those who want to own more than they presently
have
(which might be some or none at all) - shown by the demand for
additional
stock (excess demand) labelled XD
above. Offer and XD intersect
at the trading price (Pe) and Qt of land (or stocks and shares) change
hands between buyers and sellers.

When all these trades have been made, the present owners are
now
willing to go on owning land at the present price, and are not willing
to sell any.

Share Prices and Stock Market price movements.
So, what is a stock or share (or piece of land) worth? The simple
answer first - it is worth whatever someone else will pay for it.
The current market price of the share, or piece of land, or any other
physical
asset, is as good an estimate of what it is worth as you can get.
The current price reflects the total demand (reservation and excess
demand)
matched with the fixed available supply. The price will change,
as
in all markets,
only if demand shifts or supply shifts. For land
and stock markets, the shifts in total supply are usually pretty
trivial
compared with the total stock. So it is shifts in demand which
are
critical in determining prices in these stock markets.
What will shift the demand curve for land (or stocks and shares) and
hence change their prices?
- expectations of future annual returns - if these expectations
increase,
then demand for the asset will increase - shift upwards and to the
right, pushing
up
the asset price
- expectations of future selling price (market price) for the asset
- it
is expected to become more valuable in the future than it is now -
which
also pushes up the current market price
The two values are related because the market price can be interpreted
as the market buyers expectations of future earnings or returns.
- The market price of an asset (P) is the present value of
its expected
future earnings stream, as anticipated by the people trading the
asset
in the stock market.
- This present value discounts future earnings because:
- we have to wait to get them - the risk-free rate or return or
discount
rate (r)
- we need to cover the expected inflation rate in the future (p)
- we need a premium to cover the uncertainty (risk) associated
with this
future stream (u)
- The discount rate (or interest rate) i can thus
be
thought
of as being made up of three components: the real risk-free rate of
return
(r), the expected inflation rate (p) and the risk premium (u).
- For any perpetual asset - whose returns are expected
to
continue
indefinitely at some fixed value (R) - the Present Value = R/i,
the best example is a government undated bond - a consol - which
guarantees a specific annual return for ever (undated) (£4 per
year for a 4% consol (denominated in £100 units). The
trading price of this 4% consol, which is as near risk free as one can
get, is 4 ÷ the rate of interest. Or, better, the current
market risk free interest rate is well proxied by the coupon value of
the consol (4 in this case) ÷ stock market price of the consol
(PV). e.g. 14.11.07, price of Gilt: Con4%Perp (Consol paying £4
per £100 per year Perpetually) was £82, implying a market
interest rate of 4 ÷ 82 = 4.88% (somewhat lower than the present
short-term (overnight, 3 month, one year) interest rates)
The key relationships can be illustrated through this perpetual asset:
PV
= R/i = Market Price of the asset:
- If the return is fixed (assumed to be known and given) at R, then
an
increase
in the price of the asset implies a lower rate of return (as a % annual
payment) - as asset prices increase, their internal rates of return
fall (other things being equal)
- If returns are expected to increase, then we would expect the
price of
the asset to increase, given the discount rate as the opportunity cost
of capital - the rate of return we can earn on other alternative assets.
- If the interest rate in the economy increases, then the
opportunity
cost
of capital increases, and asset prices will fall.
So, if a particular company discovers a new recipe for making profits,
its annual returns (R) will be expected to increase, and its share
price
will increase until the internal rate of return falls back in line with
the market rate of interest - given the risk and inflation element of
the
company. Conversely, if the company falls on hard times, because
its market is shrinking or because it is being badly managed, its
returns
will fall and its share price will fall as well, until the internal
rate
of return is once more in line with the market rate.
Suppose we do not expect rents to remain constant in the
future.
What might they do? They might be expected to increase (or fall)
by some average and constant amount each year (say plus or minus £A
per year). In this case, the relevant sum for the present value
of
this stream of future rents (annual returns) becomes:
PV = R/i + A/i2 , where R is the basic rent
or annual return (expected this year) and A is the amount by which we
expect
this annual return to change each year in the future, and i is the
discount
rate (the opportunity cost of capital - what we could earn elsewhere,
investing
in something else). So, if we expect returns to fall, the present
value is reduced compared with the simple sum which assumes the return
stays constant. But, if we expect returns to increase, then the
present
value increases, too.
Or, we might expect a continual percentage change in the annual
return,
say plus or minus g% per year. In this case, the PV sum
becomes:
PV = R/(i - g), so that, if the expected growth rate (g) in
the returns on this asset are higher than the opportunity cost of
capital
(i), the present value for this asset goes to infinity: there
is
no price it is not
worth paying for such an asset - which is an
explanation
of why share prices shoot upwards for companies expected to do very
well
in the future.
Depreciating assets - ones that wear out.
So, how do we account for the fact that physical plant and equipment
wears out and becomes obsolete? By making an allowance for the
depreciation
of the asset - the continual re-investment necessary to maintain it in
a non-depreciating state. Suppose that this depreciation rate is
d%.
The gross return we need to get from this asset needs to cover this
depreciation
rate, so the net return we need to get on any depreciating asset is the
gross return minus the estimated depreciation rate. So, the gross
return we expect to get should be i = r + p + u + d on these
assets.
So what for
the agricultural land market?
4. For some further
(verbal/qualitative) analysis of this complexity and its implications
see: "Is Economics part of the problem?
An incomplete review" (paper by DRH to a recent conference, Prague,
Sept. 2011)
Back to Index