CLASS NOTES 4: U.S FARM POLICY
Resume:
- US a natural exporting, commercial (if originally
traditional
family)
farm system, in a country committed to individual liberty and (+/-)
free
trade, [c.f. Europe]
- 2000 % PSE around 22 - 25% for the US ($50bn. total), c.f. EU of
38 -
42%
($100bn. total) [Canada 17 - 19% ($4.3bn total); Japan, 62 - 64%
($56bn. total)] (differences between natural exporter, with no
substantial
peasant sector, and a natural importers with substantial small farm
sectors).
- Hence, policy designed to work with the market - any support
provided
largely
through exchequer payments (though not in dairy!).
- Extensive R&D and extension - land grant colleges - +
credit
support,
crop insurance, and infrastructure provision.
- Loan rates - to support and assist market price
recovery
and recovery
of producer confidence in the 30s (CCC as implementation authority)
- Needed set-aside, to control production levels as loan
rates
set
above market prices (+ some export assistance and subsidy)
- Food Problem confined to the poor - less well supported by
social
security
than in Europe, and provided with food stamp programme - conditional
(and
thus paternalistic) support - spend the government support on food, or
loose it.
- 1970s -> food shortage scares: deficiency payments
to
secure
future supplies, both against domestic food shortages and also to
capitalise
on strong world markets.
- Environmental Pressures (limited c.f.Europe, and more
focused on
Natural Resources than on landscape etc.) dealt with via paid
Conservation
Reserve programmes and sod buster/swamp buster provisions outlawing
reclaimation
of sensitive areas in response to market or policy incentives.
- Falling world prices in 80s ->
- Loan rates reduced (to 85% of Olympic moving average) -
otherwise
simply
supporting world market prices (FSA, 85 and FACT, 90)
- increasing DP costs; limited by freezing payment
base
(then
reducing this base to 85% of eligible) (FSA, 85 and FACT, 90)
- Budget pressure (1995) (+ pressure from URAA on amber/blue box
measures)
-> freezing the payment per farm, and setting time-limit on
payments
(FAIR, 1996) - Production Flexibility Contracts - and supposed
phasing
out of federal support?
- But, falling world prices led to additional emergency assistance
payments,
as well as the traitional marketing loan and deficiency payments on
non-programme
crops, during 1998 - 2002, which more than doubled federal support.
- 2002: no budget pressure - because of sustained boom over late
90s, and
now the apparent need to prevent a major depression - and
depressed
world prices, + strong vested interests with considerable and
differentiated
political clout -> strong pressure to continue support.
- What might stop this??
- External pressure - Millenium round of the WTO - limits on Blue
Box,
and
further constraints on Green Box??
- Internal Pressures:
- Taxpayers demands for other spending (only really effective
if the
Federal
Budget is under pressure, which seems unlikely for a while)
- Taxpayers concerns over equity, justice, fairness of these
payments?
- Constituency (farmer) pressures arising from the realisation
that these
payments simply increase costs for expanders and new entrants?
- The 20/80 rule - 20% receiving 80% of support approximately,
may cause
increasing friction over time.
- While US appeared to be leading the way to sensible policy reform
in
1995
FAIR, its true colours are now re-appearing: 2002 FSRIA - if we are
rich
enough (no serious budget constraint) then we will continue to support
existing vested interests, especially when (world) markets appear to be
behaving badly, regardless of what the rhetoric in WTO etc. might say.
The 2002 Farm Bill FSRIA : - [the following taken verbatim from the
conclusions
of the 2002 farm bill notes in the US
Farm Policy set]
What effects will FSRIA Have?
- Tendency to increase production (increase in the coupled effects
over
FAIR)
- Substantially increase Government spending on farm support.
- Exhaust, if not exceed, WTO limits on AMS payments, which are
likely to
be tightened eventually under the Doha round. The FSRIA does
include
a provision which charges the Secretary of State with the responsibilty
for compliance with WTO provisions - which means, in effect, that the
adminstration
has the authority to alter payment rates and conditions in the event
that
payments exceed the WTO limits (either as now set or as possibly
altered
under a new WTO agreement). However, such authority will still
remain
more or less subject to Congress ratification.
- Substantially undermines the capacity of the US to lead further
WTO
reforms,
and encourages other countries, including the EU to offer even more
resistance
to liberalisation than otherwise.
See Here for a recent analysis of
the effects of US Dairy Policy.
Pressures for future (continued) reform?
- The Budgetary Cost - as and when the budget ceiling
comes
down,
and pressure on federal spending increases, so there will be
considerable
proessure on these rather expensive and demonstrably inefficient and
inequitable
programmes. The Environmental Working Group (EWG - a non-profit
environmental
research organisation) in the US has already published on its web-site
the names and addresses of indivuduals and firms obtaining government
payments,
and the amounts each gets. As and when the US electorate becomes fully
aquainted with these data, one can expect that the political pressures
may alter somewhat from those exhibited during the drafting and
agreement
of FSRIA. The top 20% of recipients claimed 85% of the total payments
between
1996 and 2001. Senate critics of the farm bill are already trying
to tighten payment limits under the 2003 Agricultural Appropriations
Bill
- which actually authorises annual payments.
- International (WTO) Pressure - as the Doha round
proceeds,
the international
aspirations of the US might be expected to increase in saliance
compared
with the domestic concerns which clearly drove FSRIA. As they do,
so there will be increased pressure on this level of support.
- Internal Farm Level Pressures? How long can it be
before the
sensible farmers in the US realise that these generous payments simply
result in increased demand for limited farm assets, especially land,
and
that, as a result, the payments simply drive up the costs of commercial
operation of farms, rather than improving farm returns? In
addition,
how long can farm pressure groups sustain the illogical and
inconsistent
argument that these payments help to preserve rural communities and
encourage
rural development? Not for long, if the EWG and other similar
organisations
begin to challenge these spurious arguments. Ultimately FSRIA is
clearly unsustainable - it is a final (or at least one of the last)
roars
of a political dinosaur - doomed to extinction - the only real question
is when.
- When?
- When world prices recover (a time which has now been delayed by
FSRIA),
- When the political balance between the US international and
domestic
interests
revert to more favour to international concerns
- When the political balance between competing groups and parties
within
the US democratic system provide more favour to non-farm interests
- When the budget runs out.
- When will that be? Maybe in 2007. Watch this space!
- When it does - what then? Given this experience,
the
next
reform of US policy seems very likely to have to take serious account
of
two vitally important componants of reform:
- stability of world commodity markets - how can this be
improved
and how can some security be provided to an inevitably atomistic sector
(many relatively small producers - despite the apparently large size of
many farms) which is otherwise vulnerable to small excess supplies
leading
to dramatic falls in prices?
compensation for reduced support - since elimination of
support
will inevitably undermine present asset values and bankrupt otherwise
efficient
farmers?
2007 Farm Bill: Johanns
Prepares Farmers for Lower Subsidies (January, 2007)
While no details are so far available, the 2007 Farm Bill that will be
introduced next month is likely to call for less spending on farm
supports, Agriculture Secretary Mike Johanns hinted during an address
to the American Farm Bureau Federation's annual meeting in Salt Lake
City on Monday (8.1.07). "Good policy must take into account much more
than dollar count," Johanns said. "It must be tailored to provide
strong support that is relevant to current trends and forward-looking
for future growth." If the 2002 Farm Bill had simply been
renewed, as many farm organizations preferred, the dollar figure would
have dropped by as much as $20 billion, he noted, due to stronger crop
markets. Crop subsidies reached a peak in fiscal 2000, a
lackluster year, at $32 billion, and declined as farms became more
productive and profitable, with subsidies now at the $20 billion level.
Renewable energy has introduced a new market for key crops and while it
has put pressure on the livestock industries, it has been good for
farmers overall, Johanns said, adding that he expects the livestock
industry to 'adjust' to high corn, soybean and other feed prices.
Farm spending is likely to shift from subsidies to providing higher
loan limits for beginning farmers, Johanns said. That would bring the
United States into closer harmony with international trade standards;
Canada, Brazil and the European Union have filed complaints with the
World Trade Organization in recent times over protectionist behavior in
the U.S. agricultural sector, Johanns said. He also said the bill
is likely to address inequities in subsidies, 54 percent of which goes
to the top 15 percent of farms by size and sales. About 60 percent of
farmers, generally smaller, family operations, receive no direct
subsidies at all.
See, also, recent
report/comment
Back to Index