Canadian Farm Policies: (including update to
present (2004))
The notes provided
give a fair amount of detail on the history of Canadian policies.
In outline:
- Canada a relatively new country, established as definitely
different from the US;
- Geographically separated, with grain basket well reomoved from
both doemstic and offshore markets
- Transport (rail)
a critical element in early days -> grain freight rate control
(Crow's Nest Pass)
- Grain production subject to both production and market
variability -> insurance,
stabilisation & marketing
policy (CWB)
- Rapid settlement -> cooperation
(grain pools and collective
action (CWB again))
- Eastern Canada (dairy, intensive livestock) more European in
structure -> organised and managed
marketing (supply control and formula pricing) - a divided
policy, with west more inclined to (organised) markets and east more
inclined to managed markets
Statutory
freight rates (1899/1925) -> inevitable subsidy by Government
(rail cars and track maintenance) in time -> pressure on use of
budgetary funds and questions about the sense of encouraging export of
raw grain rather than local processing (through livestock), &
challenge through WTO -> eventual elimination of statutory rates,
with compensation to grain farmers (1995)
Grain Marketing (CWB) grew
from Grain Coops (Wheat Pools), pooled prices and delivery quotas,
established in 1935, monopoly power in 1943, with government guaranteed
initial payments (set by Federal Government), though with virtually no
direct subsidy element -> conflicts with US grain trade on formation
of NAFTA and elimination of tariff protection - ongoing - see CBC news story
(March 2003). For an in-depth analysis of the costs and benefits
of single-desk-selling (CWB) versus export subsidy (US), see Alston & Gray, "State Trading
versus Export subsidy: the case of Canadian Wheat", Journal of
Agricultural and Resource Economics, 25, 1, 52 - 67, 2000 - the results
are rather ambiguous, and depend on particular circumstances (including
the extent to which other policies are used to assist farmers.)
Insurance:
Crop insurance (with producer contributions) for crop failures ->
Gross Revenue Insurance Plan (GRIP) 1991 - 1995, based on 15 yr. moving
average of gross revenues, which proved too costly for Provincial
governments (bearing 25% of cost, in contrast to previous crop
insurance programmes, where provincial government contributions were
lower, discontinued in 1995/6 -> developed into: The Canadian
Farm Income Program
(CFIP) provides funds to producers who have had a sudden and severe
drop in income for reasons beyond their control such as flooding,
disease, price collapse, or rapidly rising input costs. CFIP is a whole
farm three-year program covering the 2000, 2001, and 2002 claim years,
and is delivered by the Federal Government, without provincial
participation, and without any producer contribution. This
programme
applies to any farmer reporting a business loss to the Canadian Inland
Revenue. It is designed to cover 70% of an historic average
margin
(over last five years), and, in essence, pays out the difference
between the current margin (farm revenues less allowable costs,
excluding capital and other investment payments etc.) and the reference
margin (70% of the historic average).
Stabilisation:
Price stabilisation (ASA) -> margin stabilisation with producer
contributions (WGSA) -> Net Income Stabilisation Account (NISA),
voluntary producer contributions to individual stabilisation account,
with more than matching Federal government contributions to the account
- to be drawn down as and when farm incomes fall (at producer's
discretion). However, accounts were used as pension funds, rather than
stabilisation accounts, and government contributions not achieving the
economic stabilisation effects anticipated, while being commited to
funding the NISA (and CFIP) accounts
Current Policy ->
Consolidation of stabilisation and disaster (insurance) policies as
part of a more general Agricultural Policy
Framework (2003) - billed as "an Agricultural Policy for the 21st.
Century".
The following statement comes from Agriculture and Agri-Food
Canada's first edition of the new Policy
Framework Newsletter.
"Since 2001, federal, provincial and
territorial governments have been working with the agriculture and
agri-food industry to help strengthen and revitalize the sector through
a new Agricultural Policy Framework (APF) for Canada. Over the next
five years, Canadian farmers will have new tools, services and options
to strengthen their businesses, increase prosperity and meet the
demands of consumers at home and abroad. The policy framework brings
together five key elements—
- Business Risk Management (CAIS below)
- Environment,
- Food Safety and Quality,
- Renewal,
- Science and Innovation
—in a single, solid platform that
will help Canadian agriculture maximize new opportunities in world
markets. No other country can lay claim to such a cohesive and
integrated policy approach to agriculture. For Canada, there will be
international recognition as the world leader in food safety and
quality, environmentally responsible production and innovative
products."
The Government of Canada has now signed the APF Framework Agreement
with all provinces and territories (see second Agri-Info
(the Agricultural policy Framework Newletter, August, 2003).
Canadian
Agricultural Income Stabilisation (CAIS) programme (2002),
CAIS is intended to consolidate both income stabilisation and disaster
payments - made when farm incomes fall dramatically, because of, e.g.
disease outbreaks etc.)
Participating producers choose a deposit level of contigency funds
(with recognised financial organisations (banks etc.)) which then
triggers government funds to make good payouts from the individual farm
fund, triggered when eligible (taxable) incomes fall below a reference
income or margin (based on last five years, excluding highest and
lowest).
Graph A (from the
CAIS page above) illustrates the three tiers of cost-sharing under the
integrated
income stabilization and protection program. The first 15 percent of a
drop in income below the historical reference margin would be
cost-shared
equally between government and the producer. The next 15-percent loss
would bring $2.33 from government for every farmer dollar. The portion
of
decline below 70 percent of the reference margin, considered an
income disaster, would bring $4 from government for each farm dollar.
Producers effectively buy into a level of protection according to their
contingency fund (producer contribution) - the more they deposit in
their CAIS account, the more they stand to benefit from the scheme -
based on the historical margins generated by their farms.
Producers who participate have to commit to a deposit equaling at least
14 percent of their reference margin. This would fully cover income
drops of up to 40 percent of the reference margin, while returning 70
percent of the reference margin if the margin fell to zero in the claim
year. (see link above)
Maximum protection, guaranteeing full coverage for margin declines of
up to 65 percent and returning 92 percent of the reference margin if
the claim-year margin falls to zero, could be obtained for a deposit of
22 percent of the reference margin.
See here for a very full and
detailed assessment of this programme, carried out for Agriculture and
Agri-Food Canada by a consortium of consultants, which generally
supports this new programme (limited only by the extent to which
government is prepared to contribute to releif payments). This
assessed the new programme against "the objectives set out by
Agriculture Ministers for business risk management programming, as
follows:
• to ensure programs are responsive to demand and that government
dollars are directed to areas of need with respect to income
stabilization, disaster mitigation, insurance coverage and investment;
• to provide equal treatment for farmers across Canada facing similar
risk situations;
• to minimize the distortion of farmers’ production and marketing
decisions;
• to focus on management of risks related to the stability of the
entire farm and to avoid duplication of payments;
• to be relatively simple and easy to understand; and
• to facilitate long term planning by farmers.”
Some highlights of this assessment:
- The cap for the CAIS is that the total government payment cannot
exceed 70% of a farmer’s calculated loss in Production Margin (their
word for the reference margin). This is to help ensure that the program
meets WTO requirements.
- In CAIS, the government’s portion is only due when the income is
taken. Therefore, governments do not incur a liability until a payment
is triggered, and farmers will not be able to build and hold balances
as with NISA. They must take the money when it is triggered.
- The NISA program provided for a trigger of the account when
income (specifically defined on a cash basis and incorporating off-farm
income) fell below $30,000 for the year. This element of program design
is considered a “support” component rather than a “stabilization”
component and has not been incorporated into the CAIS.
- CAISprovides more income stability than the previous (NISA)
program in all three sets of analysis (based on NISA farm data, model
farm simulations, and “real” farm data)
- CAIS consistently provides more stability than the previous
program when the aggregate NISA farms are disaggregated by type of
farm, region, size of farm, or size of margin.
- The version of the industry proposal that was analysed resulted
in better measures of stability for some industries and disaggregations
than does CAIS. However, the cost of the industry proposal is
significantly greater than CAIS.
- In conclusion: "We conclude that while the proposed new program
has advantages and disadvantages compared to the current programs, on
balance, it is clear to us that the proposed new programs better
achieve the six objectives of business risk management as agreed to by
the Federal and Provincial Ministers in Whitehorse."
For
future resolution?
- CWB's place and role -
status as a monopsonist - single desk seller, or "state trading
enterprise" (hardly state, since it is wholly producer owned) remains
problematic, both in terms of NAFTA and the WTO, as well as having to
compete with the US market for Canadian supplies.
- Supply Managed commodities
(dairy, eggs and poultry) still subject to pressure to become more
market oriented against considerable producer and constituency
resistance.
- Development of Agricultural
Policy Framework, including experience with CAIS and related
programmes.
- However, Canadian agricultural policy generally moving in the
direction of freer trade and compatibility with WTO and external
pressures (especially from the US) - though expect considerable
frictions between Canadian and US grain farmers (especially), in terms
of the support levels provided by the US under the 2003 farm act.
Japanese Policy and Update
Again, notes provide a
good deal of the historical and geographical context and development of
Japanese policy. In outline:
- Limited agricultural land, with large farm population ->
natural importer
- Strong pressure of food security (and thus drive for
self-sufficiency) from both geography and history
- Post WWII land reforms - redistributing large estates to small
tenants - coupled with political reform introducing democracy ->
political power to peasant farmers.
- Rapid non-agricultural growth, coupled with farm structure
dominated by small farms (and strong cooperatives (NOKYO) -> strong
pressure for farm support
- History of government control -> state trading and formula
pricing rather than market manipulation and direct intervention through
subsidy and import taxes.
- 1961 Agricultural Basic Law: to achieve:
- Parity of farm and non-farm incomes
- Self Sufficiency in major foodstuffs (selective expansion in
line with
growth in demand)
- Improvement of productivity (through expansion of farm size
into viable
units)
- Through:
- Price stabilisation and support (based on cost of production
formula
pricing) - e.g rice (and need for set-aside as rice policy achieves
(uniquely for Japan) excess supply, and continuing small and
increasingly part-time farms.
- Import protection (especially quotas and non-tariff barriers)
and state
trading.
- farmer training, rural infrastructure and structural support
- High levels of protection, but very limited progress towards
self-sufficiency (because of poor farm structures, and high land prices
(from non-agricultural pressure).
- Led to considerable evolution of the farm problem:
- farm incomes adjust through non-farm activities - farmers no
longer poor relative to rest of population
- support policies become increasingly expensive, and fail to
meet objectives (either generating unwanted surpluses or unsustainable
set-asides (rice) or failing to improve self-sufficiency), exacerbated
by land policies which encourage farming use, and restrict farm
amalgamations, capitalising benefits of farm support into land values
and hence increasing resistance to change.
- increasing pressure from trading partners (vitally important
for Japan)
- changing political preferences and changes in political power
of Iron Triangle (NOKYO, bureaucrats and traditional ruling
political party (LPD)
- slower domestic growth and increasing competition from NICs of
pacific rim -> more pressure on budgetary spending on farm
programmes, and on high share of food consumption in domestic spending
- -> pressure for change in policy (lower rice prices,
substitution of tariffs for state trading and import quotas)
Current Position
"Despite being a major
beneficiary from multilateral market-opening measures in manufacturing,
Japan continues to resist opening its agricultural markets. This
position is becoming increasingly untenable multilaterally, especially
following the inclusion of
agriculture into the World Trade Organisation (WTO) during the Uruguay
Round." (Trewin et al.,
"Moving Japanese Agriculture Forward" in a report (Issues, Options and
Strategies for improving Japanese Agricultural Trade Policies) for the
(Australian) Rural
Industries Research and Development Corporation by the
Australian-Japan Research Centre (Nov. 2000))
See, also, ABARE, (Bull 7
Roberts) Agricultural Trade Policies in Japan: The Need for reform
(2001), for a very comprehensive account of current Japanese policy and
agricultural performance (from the critical perspective of the
Australians). (this is large pdf file - 102 pages.).
Domestic rice marketing was
substantially deregulated in 1995 (following the URAA), although rice
imports continued to be controlled by the Food Agency until 1999, rice
stocks increased as imports of rice were forced through the URAA access
agreement. In 1999, Japan converted quantity restrictions on rice
imports into a (high to virtually prohibitive) tariff, which does
nothing to resolve the rice market problems (continued high domestic
prices, surplus production and restriction of imports) expected to be a
major issue in the Doha (development) round of WTO negotiations). (see Honma, New Agricultural Basic Law,
from RIRDC report above, page 17 - 36, which includes the provisions of
the New Law.)
A New Basic Law
for Agriculture was passed by the Japanese parliament in
1999. One article of this new law (30) states that "the
state shall take necessary measures for allowing the prices of farm
products to form appropriately, reflecting the real supply/demand
situation and quality evaluation in order to promote agricultural
production responsive to consumer demands" - indicating a more market
oriented focus for new policy.
On the other hand, this article also provides that "the state shall
take necessary measures for mitigating the adverse effects of
significant price changes of farm products on farm management", which
appears to negate any market reform intentions. In addition, the new
basic law continues to set self-sufficiency targets, implying continued
market intervention, and embraces (article 35) the concepts of
multifunctionality (as in Europe) and the associated implication that
this justifies continued support.
The New Law does provide for some land reform (joint purchase by
farmers seeking cooperative management and operation of farms), while
and amendment to the Farmland Law in 2000 allows joint stock companies
to purchase land, although effective control is retained by farmers.
The general concensus (mostly from Australia, admittedly) seems to be
that the New Basic Law does not really alter the general focus of
Japanese policy very much, and that much remains to be done to bring
policy into line with Japan's major trading partners. Shogenji - a professor in the Graduate
School of Agriculture and Life Sciences, University of Tokyo - writing
in the (Japanese) Government Auditing Review (March 2003), also
concludes that the present reforms do not go nearly far enough,
indicating that there is some authoratative criticism of the policy
within Japan [this article is not an easy read, since the standard of
translation is mediocre at best].
Some apparent points from Shogenji's review:
- The target for self-sufficiency (45% of calorie supply) was
subject to considerable debate before inclusion in the Law, with MAFF
being reluctant to include such a target, although it was concerned to
encourage (assist?) improvements in farm production and productivity
- The Basic Law represents a continuing debate (and
therefore possible evolution) about the relative roles of the
market ("The phrase “shall take necessary measures” can be
paraphrased more properly as “the government is moving in the direction
of refraining from excessive involvement in the market.” and "There is
also a belief that this change encourages production to meet with
demand, resulting in an improvement in the self-sufficiency rate in the
long term.") and the proper role of government (mitigating adverse
price changes, and assisting multifunctionality), interpreted by
Shogenji as dealing with market failures.
- Shogenji deals especially with three policy measures:
deregulation of domestic markets (wheat and soybeans); price supports
and safety-net policies (echoing Canada); direct payments (echoing EU
and US)
- Market
Deregulation (of wheat and soybeans) - to a "bidding mechanism"
(presumably managed by the Food Agency - led to lower domestic prices,
because of imports, and the use of fixed payments to bridge the gap
between the old prices and the new - as in the EU. However,
Shogenji is not convinced that the bidding system (currently limited to
rather narrow price ranges) properly reflects genuine market signals,
and hence will not generate appropriate adjustments in quality - supply
adjusting to what the market wants. In addition, the fixed
payment element is still coupled, thus supply response to market
demands is limited. Furthermore, a part of the justification for
continued subsidy - the fixed payment - is to encourage the
diversification of rice paddy land, and is paid for any and all wheat
production on this land, further divorcing the incentive from market
requirements. "Can we say that the negative side of bureaucratic policy
formation emerges
when the wheat price policies are controlled by Food Agency, and the
subsidy measures to the wheat for crop change are controlled by
Agricultural Production Bureau (currently Production Bureau)?"
- Price
Supports and Safety Nets. A "Measure for Stabilising Farm
Income" (MSFI) emerged subsequent to the Basic Law, in response to
declining rice prices, and also to rapid increases in vegetable imports
from China. However, it is currently a slogan/idea rather than a well
thought out policy, mixing the ideas of stabilisation and insurance
with others of price support and protection. Shogenji favours an
insurance/stabilisation scheme at the whole farm level (Canada), but
not the price support (which is the most attractive part ot the
farmers, of course - but make "discussions surrounding the MSFI
meaningless".) Shogenji also argues strongly for widening policy to
include rural development assistance, to encourage the adjustment of
farming to a market based system.
- Direct
Payments: e.g. "(CAP) of the EU. They can be broadly
classified into: (1)
direct payments as compensation for price cut of farm products; (2)
direct payments for maintaining and promoting positive
externalities of agriculture and controlling the negative
externalities." "The Japanese agricultural policies under reform are
moving towards these types of direct payment as a new policy
method." But:
- Japanese payments are dependent on continued use of the land
(in rice in disadvantaged areas), and on community agreement - based on
the community management of the rice irrigation and village activity in
farming rice in these disadvantaged areas - in effect, a continued
payment for the preservation of the rice-based village community.
- Another direct payment is for dairy farming relying on local
grazing (rather than on imported feed), to minimise pollution. Shogenji
criticises this policy as being too crude to accurately reflect the
costs of pollution (or benefits of non-pollution), though recognises
the possibility of continued adjustment of rates and conditions to
improve this.
- Government
Failure: Shogenji suggests that the key problems with
Japanese agricultural policy stem from government (or policy) failure,
rather than market failure. Specifically, he identifies:
- Failure to define specific targets for policy, and hence
failure to identify appropriate instruments.
- Failure to count adminstrative (transactions) costs, and hence
policies which potentially cost more than they deliver.
- conflicting policy objectives (market encouragement versus
income or margin support) leading to conflicting policy incentives and
instruments - exacerbated in Japan by "sectional bureaucracies" rather
than a general strategy (Canada and EU).
The
Future? One view of Japanese policy is that it is still at an
early stage of modern evolution, subject to the same pressures as
elsewhere, but yet to adapt its basic structures and attitudes as much
as Canada or the EU. It retains a sense of central regulation and
control, and hence dependency on bureaucracy, while also finding it
difficult to wean agriculture (and associated village communities) from
dependence on government support and protection. Yet (e.g. Shogenji)
there may be signs that debate and discussion of these issues is
increasing, as would be expected from the internal and external
pressures on the policy. If so, expect further, and perhaps rapid
policy adjustment in the future.
Back
to AEF362 Index.