INTRODUCTION TO SUSTAINABLE LIVELIHOODS
Index of material:
- The Sustainable Livelihoods approach.
- A personal (DRH) view.
1. Sustainable Livelihoods
Approach (Ellis & DFID)
There is no unique and commonly accepted version of the development
process.
One framework which is currently gaining acceptance is that developed
by
the Department for International Development (UK), DFID, called the sustainable
livelihoods framework (DFID, Sustainable Rural
Livelihoods, ed.
Diana Carney, 1998). This approach is also explored in some detail by
Frank Ellis: Rural Livelihoods and Diversity in
Developing Countries, Oxford University Press,
2000.
This approach has now taken over, in the
international
development field, from the the earlier Integrated Rural
Development
approach,
which, interestingly, still seems to dominate much of the developed
(European
Union) discussion of rural development. (See here for the official DFID
Guidance sheets on Sustainable Livelihoods approach, introduced by this overview (pdf file) and a contrast
with the previous Integrated Rural Development programme framework).
The starting point is a definition
of sustainable livelihoods
(following
from Robert Chambers and Gordon Conway):
"A Livelihood comprises the capabilities, assets
(including both material and social resources) and activities
required
for a means of living. A Livelihood is sustainable when it can cope
with and recover from stresses and shocks and
maintain
or enhance its capabilities and assets both now and in the future,
while
not undermining the natural resource (NR) base."
Capabilities (Sen, 1997): "contrast between two
distinct but related areas of investigation in understanding the
processes of economic and social development: the accumulation of
“human capital” and the expansion of “human capability.” The former
concentrates on the agency of human beings - through skill and
knowledge as well as effort - in augmenting production possibilities.
The latter
focuses on the ability of human
beings to lead lives they have reason
to value and to enhance the substantive choices they have."
"The
set of alternative beings and doings that a person can achieve with his
or her economic, social and personal characteristics" (Ellis, p.
7, quoting Dreze and Sen, 1989). - potentially confusing overlap
between assets and activities; processes and outcomes.
Assets: (see also,
below) include claims and access in addition to recognised
economic assets: typically classified as
- natural,
- social (community
networks,
including informal and personalised networks - see, e.g. Harriss & De Renzio, 1997, also, the Civic
Practices Network),
- human
(education, skills and health),
- financial
(including access to credit)
- physical
(built plant, tools and equipment).
Access (controlled by social
norms
and rules) is an important attribute to the asset holdings by
any
household, and emphasises the role of social relations and institutions.
Ellis's
Definition: (p 10) "A
livelihood comprises the assets (natural, physical, human,
financial and social capital), the activities,
and the access to these
(mediated by institutions and social relations) that together determine
the living gained by the individual or household." where the dynamic nature is also to
be emphasised - livelihoods adapt
and adjust, and hence evolve
through time in response to changing conditions and
circumstances. Asset stocks change, as do availability and
access.
[Incomes: different
income categories (farm, off-farm, non-farm, transfers &
remittances, rental) reflect different labour (and capital) markets.
-> the outcome of the livelihood strategy and activities, and asset
base]
Diversity:
the range of income sources in the household 'portfolio'. Diversification:
the creation of diversity as an ongoing socio-economic process
reflecting both pressures and opportunities. "the process by which
households construct an increasingly diverse portfolio of activities
and assets in order to survive and improve their standard of living. "
(p 15).
Entitlements:
(p17) 'the set of alternative bundles of consumption goods
over which a person can establish command given the prevailing legal,
political and economic arrangements' (Dreze and Sen, 1989), or the
exercise of asset deployment which can generate command over
commodities and goods. Includes rights and
claims and privileges associated with command over consumption, but is
wider in that it also includes household capacities.
The
Focus: Households or Families? (Ellis, p 18 -
21) Households, here, mean "the resident social unit, extended
where applicable to include migrants and others who make intermittent
or
regular contributions to household welfare" (p21) [or can claim
entitlement to household welfare. Rural homesteads diverse in two
main directions (axes): concentrated/resident
(no migrants - remittances or claims from a distance) to dispersed; simple, single family or extended, multiple family ->
four way classification of 'households'.
The
Sustainable Livelihoods Framework (SLF):
The following outline is a summary of this
framework
(SLF). "The asset status of
poor individuals and households is fundamental to understanding the
options open to them, the strategies they adopt for survival, and their
vulnerability to adverse trends and events. Poverty policy should be
about raising the asset status of the poor, or enabling existing assets
that are idle or unproductive to be used productively." (Ellis,
p 28).

Assets,
also known as resources, or capitals, include investments for
the
future (including surpluses, or retained earnings from previous
periods, as well as training, education, networks etc.), stores or
stocks
of physical capital, and claims which can be exercised on others.
"most of the anomalies between the lists of different researchers can
be resolved through the classification as Natural, Physical,
Social, Human and Financial." (Ellis, p 32).
Natural Capital
comprises
land, water, biodiversity, environmental resources etc. - [which could
be called the natural
circumstance
of the community or household], of varying agro-ecological potential,
and differentiated between renewable and non-renewable (mostly mineral)
resources.
Social Capital includes the social
institutions
(rules and habits) and associated trust and networks [the history
(context)
and
culture of the community] - "the reciprocity within
communities and between households based on trust deriving from social
ties" - see Harriss& De Renzio, 1997
- which can
also be described as vertical
linkages (authority relationships (parent/child) and social
responsibilities of the better-off, with associated claims by the less
well-off) as well as horizontal
linkages in voluntary and kinship networks. Exclusion from these
networks and reciprocal trust relationships clearly presents
potentially serious problems for the excluded. The literature
distinguishes three major types/forms: Bonding (horizontal
associations such as family and kinship ties, and common
language); Bridging (communications networks etc. which connect
seperate bonded groups); Linking (which generates and encourages
respect, recognition of mutual dependence, inclusion, reciprocity etc.,
and exchange)
Harriss and de Renzio (1997) argue that Social Capital can be further
divided usefully into:
- family and kinship
connections - relating to the single household, the extended
family, or the clan, based on `strong' ties of blood and
affinity;
- (wider) social networks,
or 'associational life' - relating to groups and organizations
that link individuals belonging to different families or kinship groups
in common activities for different purposes. These probably constitute
the form ofsocial capital closest to its more common de®nition in
terms of `networks of civic engagement', or `local
associations';
- cross-sectional linkages,
or `contacts spanning differences in sector and power' -
we may refer to these as `networks of networks' that link together
organizations belonging to different sectors of society (NGOs,
grassroots organizations, govern-
ment agencies, private ®rms) in the search for solutions to complex
problems, by combining different resources and different kinds of
knowledge. Cross-sectoral linkages are the realm of `complementarity'
in the form of `mutually supportive relations between public and
private actors' and of `coproduction';
- political capital
- constituted by the norms and networks that shape the relations
between civil society and the state, giving a society the capability to
mediate con¯ict by hearing, channelling, and composing multiple
citizen demands. `Political capital' relates to the informal
institutional arrangements that may lead, on the one hand, to
clientelism, rent-seeking and exclusion, and on the other to effective
representation, accountability and participation. This form of social
capital is located in `political society', defined as `the range of
institutions and actors which mediate the relationships between civil
society and the state', and depends on the `embeddedness' of the former
in the latter;
- institutional and policy
framework - or the set of formal rules and norms (constitutions,
laws, regulations, policies) that regulate public life in a society
(what the World Bank has termed `macro-level social capital). This form
of social capital has somewhat of a double nature, because it can
in¯uence the formation of other forms of social capital, but it
also represents in itself a resource that facilitates co-ordinated
action by citizens;
- social norms and values-
defined by widely shared cultural beliefs and the effects these have on
the functioning of a society as a whole; (see also the discussion of
`collectivist' and `individualist' societies). Norms and values bear on
other forms of social capital as well as constituting the most general
form of social capital in themselves.
[Note it is principally via Social Capital that this
Framework seeks to integrate Sociology, Anthropology and (perhaps)
Politics with Economics so as to provide a more inclusive social
analytical framework. Perhaps not suprisingly, this attempt to
integrate very different traditions, practices and theoretical
approaches generates some antagonism - see here for a recent critique)
Human Capital includes the
skills,
training and education of the people (as workers) as well as their
health [the character of the community, as its potential for
action]
- typically the major asset of the poor. In the context of Structural
Adjustment Programmes in developing countries, with an emphasis on
government budgetary balance and liberalisation, may compromise this
asset by cost-recovery edicts for health (drugs) and education, while
in economies in transition, many of these 'services' which were
supplied through the production cooperatives have not yet been
adequately replaced by the state or public funds.
Physical
Capital is man-made, and includes the infrastructure (transport,
housing, water,
energy systems (mains electricity), sewage systems,
communications networks etc.) as well as production equipment:
factories, machines
and
tools, and also 'consumer' capital (fridges, deep-freezes, telephones,
internet connections etc.) - [the physical circumstance of the
community or household].
Financial Capital: household
savings (if any) and access to loans and credit, which "owe their role
in the asset portfolio of households to their convertibility into other
forms of capital or, indeed, directly into consumption. Fungibility, meaning ease of
switching between uses, is a fundamental characteristic of capital in
the form of cash." (p.34). But savings are often held in less liquid forms, as stocks of
livestock (goats, cattle), or as gold, food stocks etc. (especially
when financial institutions and organisations (banks etc.) are missing
or mistrusted.
Mediating Processes
Here separated into Social Relations; Institutions;
Organisations
as the conditions affecting access and transformation of
assets into Livelihoods (which are at least partly endogenous (within
the community's control) , and Shocks and Trends,
which reflect the wider contexts and circumstances (largely exogenous -
beyond the community's control) affecting livelihoods and their
generation from the base assets.
Social Relations
refers to the positioning
of individuals and households within society (e.g. Davies and Hossain, 1997), including
class, ethnicity, age, religion, caste and gender relations.
Institutions
used here
in the North (and Williamson) sense: the rules, codes, conventions and
norms by which
society governs its social, political and economic relations, see
North, Douglas C. (1990), Institutions,
Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge
University Press. - "the role of institutions is to reduce uncertainty
by establishing a stable structure to human interaction", and
generating reliable, if not always desirable or satisfactory,
expectations about behaviours and responses.
Organisations
are the formal bodies through which these authorities are
exercised - "groups of individuals bound by some common purpose
to achieve [specific?] objectives." (Ellis, quoting North, 1990, p 38)
These three aspects of human interaction are critical in determining
the deployment of assets to achieve livelihood ambitions and objectives
- "they inhibit or facilitate the exercise of capabilities and choice
by households." (Ellis, p 39).
Clearly, the levels and quality of Social
Capital possessed by households are closely related to these
mediating processes. [Indeed, the distinction between structure and
process is especially blurred and indistinct here - information on one
will typically generate information on the other, while the systems of
interaction (the processes and the structures) tend to co-evolve.]
Trends
in population, density, migration, economic performance (incomes and
growth), prices, trade flows, technological change, and structural
adjustment (changing relative importance of different sectors and
regions), will all affect household livelihood strategies, though with
varying force depending on local conditions and circumstances.
Shocks:
droughts, floods, pests and diseases, civil war [and also economic
shocks - sever depression, rapid inflation - and social upheaval (as in
some transitions between centrally-planned (communist) systems and
market -based systems], and also include local and personal shocks
(death, accident, disease, etc.).
Livelihood Strategies:
coping and adaptation behaviours
in response to the mediating factors
and predicated on the asset base, which generate the means of
living and the capacities to have a life. The strategies are revealed
by the Activities
which households follow, here classified according to their dependence
on natural resources (land and the environment). Different
portfolios of activities will be more or less vulnerable to changes,
shocks and dislocations, and differently responsive to policy
initiatives or changing market forces.
Scoones, 1998, suggests an agriculturally based typology of
strategies: Agricultural intensification or extensification
(using land more or less intensively, with more or less inputs per
hectare); Livelihood diversification (off-farm employment and
activity); Migration. But Ellis cautions against typologies, on the
grounds that the options and possibilities they (necessarily) exclude
can be more important than those they include, and that the very
process of classifying behaviours restricts attention and analysis to
the conventional practices.
Effects:
an illustration of the possible indicators of the outcomes
[interestingly, here, apparently ignoring the capacities for
growth and development except indirectly].
Ellis suggests that there are three
important behaviours (conditioned by situations etc.) which
condition the adoption of strategies:
Substitution:
Willingness and capacity to substitute different assets for one
another has an important effect on the ability of households to cope
and adapt (and thus grow). The existence of well-functioning asset and
capital markets (and thus reliable finance) are important here (see
below). "Assets that can freely be converted into cash that is
then used to purchase other assets provide considerably more
livelihood flexibility than assets which cannot be substituted in
this way" (p 42), and illustrates this with the example of the Amazon
rainforest - which cannot easily be 'capitalised' by the residents
other than by exploiting it by felling it (thus improving the land for
farming), and then using it for extensive grazing (since land is
abundant and labour scarce).
Crisis Management: Coping strategies - short term
responses to unanticipated crises - typically realise the least
important or the most mobil assets first: seek alternative income
sources (diversify); draw on social capital (claim obligations);
migrate; sell moveable and reproducible assets (livestock); sell or
abandon fixed assets (land, buildings etc.).
Adaptation: responses to longer term trends,
threats and opportunities, which result in greater capacity to resist
shocks and adverse trends (improve resilience). A diversified asset
base, and portfolio of activities [apparently in direct contrast to the
superficial edict of the market -> specialisation] is
typically more robust in the face of uncertainty and risk of
crisis.
SLF
in Practice
This Framework is not an operational manual,
it is only a conceptual framework to organise constructive
thought. The data requirements to make it operational are
enormous, and typically beyond reason. Scoones (op cit.) suggests an 'optimal ignorance'
approach: "seeking out only what is necessary to know in order for
informed action to proceed" - [what to we need to know; economical
approach - does the cost and effort of gathering more information
actually improve the analysis and decision by enough to warrant the
extra effort? Is what we already have near enough for farm
work?]
Participatory
Rural Appraisal methods "can quite quickly establish,
at the village level, the priority areas of community-wide concern,
and, from there, a phased approach can zero in on the particular
problems and constraints of sub-groups within the village." (p 47/8)
(also known as Participatory Learning and Action (Pretty
Abstract of Chambers, R, The origins
and practice of participatory rural appraisal, World
Development, 22, 7, 953 - 1102.
Participatory Rural Appraisal (PRA)
describes a growing family
of approaches and methods to enable local people to share, enhance and
analyze their knowledge of life and conditions, to plan and to act. PRA
has sources in activist participatory research, agroecosystem analysis,
applied anthropology, field research on farming systems, and rapid
rural appraisal (RRA). In RRA information is more elicited and
extracted by outsiders; in PRA it is more shared and owned by local
people. Participatory methods include mapping and modeling, transect
walks, matrix scoring, seasonal calendars, trend and change analysis,
well-being and wealth ranking and grouping, and analytical diagramming.
PRA applications include natural resources management, agriculture,
poverty and social programs, and health and food security. Dominant
behavior by outsiders may explain why it has taken until the 1990s for
the analytical capabilities of local people to be better recognized and
for PRA to emerge, grow and spread.
The key to this is empowerment of the local community - PRA will raise
expectations about what can be done, which can easily be frustrated if
power to act is not also devolved to local communities. If the process
is to be used simply to gather data (elicitive), then
expectations of the participants needs careful management. See,
also, Community
Adaptation and Sustainable Livelihoods (International Institute for
Sustainable Development, IISD), and the CASL
guidebook.
The approach focuses on the Asset Status of
the household or community, which can be represented in
qualitative terms as follows:

[The
access
which this community has to each of these fundamental capital stocks is
measured (at least conceptually) along an axis from the centre of the
pentagon
- which produces a web profile of the community's STRENGTHS and
WEAKNESSES (household,
group, region, parish, village etc.). Generally, the further any
group lies from the central point of the pentagon ("The Black Hole?"),
the more robust is it likely to be in the face of shocks and
stresses.
However, this is only a snap-shot of the current status of the
community. It does not obviously identify the OPPORTUNITIES or THREATS
which this community faces.] It is important to add the
activities portfolios and behaviours to this asset structure to get the
whole picture. "While assets focus on the potential to achieve
sustainable livelihoods, activities focus on the realisation of that
potential in the shape of a viable portfolio of income-generating
activities. If that potential cannot be realised, then
assets remain unemployed or underemployed, and an apparently robust
asset portfolio becomes unable to generate a sufficient livelihood."
(Ellis, p 50).
A
Suggested Revision (DRH):
The DfID Framework
is typically illustrated slightly differently, as follows.

The general argument and logic is identical to that suggested by
Ellis, but the feedback linkages and inter-relationships are made more
explicit in this representation.
[Here, a possible modification is suggested by DRH, as
follows. It is suggested that Spatial
Capital
is missing from the conventional representation. Where a household or
community is in relation to its neighbours, potential trading partners,
governors etc. is an important aspect of its potential. At the
scale of countries, for instance, UNCTAD notes (Globalisation
& Development: Facts and Figures, section 1.1):
Nearly all of the 31 landlocked developing countries (LLDCs)
have a low per capita GDP, reflecting a wide range of development
constraints, including small domestic markets, high vulnerability to
economic shocks and natural disasters, low levels of human resources
development, and limited domestic savings capacity.
The economic development of most LLDCs is adversely affected by
remoteness from world markets. Four LLDCs in Central Asia are located
at least 3,500 kilometres from the nearest maritime port. Another seven
LLDCs face more than 1,500 kilometres of overland transport for
merchandise, while the remaining LLDCs – with the exception of
Ethiopia, Macedonia TFYR, Malawi, Moldova, Paraguay and Swaziland – are
situated more than 1,000 kilometres from maritime ports. Given the long
distances and the structure of these countries’ exports, which are
dominated by low-value bulk commodities, freight and related transit
costs are especially burdensome and significantly reduce the potential
for export-led growth in LLDCs. These countries are also negatively
affected by the high costs of their imports.
In addition, inadequate infrastructure, poor transport organization and
a proliferation of official and non-official controls of transported
goods make it difficult for these countries to compete in markets where
just-in-time production, flexibility, speed and reliability in delivery
of products have become crucial. However, the example of prosperous
developed landlocked countries in Europe suggests that geographical
disadvantages can be overcome.
The notion of Spatial Capital (the geography and context of
the community) as a separate category of asset allows for the ideas of
peripherality and remoteness to be separated from other aspects of
social and physical capital, and includes
the state and quality of communications and transport linkages, as well
as the institutional and social relations which govern the use of and
access to these routes, to the rest of the world (country, regional
centres etc.). As such, it offers the possibility of more appropriate
conceptualisation of the remaining assets. However, this leads to a
second suggestion:
The fifth major asset category in the conventional picture - Financial - is
especially problematic. The potentially critical importance of fungibility and substitution between assets has
already been mentioned above, and leads to the obvious power of
organised and reliable capital (financial) markets and processes (often
a major differentiating feature of developed versus less developed
countries and regions). The transformation and more flexible
accumulation and improvement of real assets is frequently
strongly assisted by financial capital markets (transfers and
transactions), which allow others (more distant and richer) to take a
stake in the development of a region or community. Of course,
such opportunities also bring
threats of exploitation,
asset-stripping and loss of control and power over local assets
(financed by external capital). Of interest here, perhaps, is the
effect of WalMart® on rural
poverty in North America.
Consider the essence of financial
markets: to transfer ownership
of part or
the whole of real physical and natural assets, as the right to
receive income from the asset and benefit (or not) from any change in
the value of the asset. Loans and credit are provided by other
(richer) people to those that need additional real capital (or income
supplements) on the basis of collateral
- either as explicit transfers of ownership (prior claim) on existing
real capital (land, buildings, factories etc.) or as claims on human or
social capital (lenders' rights to claim interest and repayment from
kith and kin, or expectations of repayment from future earnings
streams). The point is, both credit access and savings are based on
existing (possibly new) real
physical, natural, social or human capital somewhere.
Credit
involves mortgaging existing owned assets to lever additional resources
from those better placed, either within or outside the community.
Savings involve lending own income to someone else in return
for periodic interest or dividend returns, with the security of
these savings depending on the continued ability and willingness of
the borrower to service and repay the loan. These
transactions and transfers are better thought of as part of the
structures and processes within which the household or community
exists, rather than as local assets in their own right. Removal of the
financial category from the asset structure of the household focuses
attention on the critically important aspects of location, ownership and
control (and hence of hazard) of the real assets of the
community. Indeed, one possible way of measuring the potential to
mobilise the real natural, physical, human, social and spatial capital is to measure the
extent to which these can be mortgaged in return for finance (borrowed
future income) to enhance existing assets. In short, finance is
really a combination of process and of social, institutional and
organisational structure, rather than an asset in its own right.
This revision of the conceptual framework is designed to both help a
more realistic picture of livelihoods, and enrich the concept by
separating processes and surrounding socio-economic environments
(social relations, institutions and organisations) from the indigenous
asset or resource base.]
Back to top
Determinants of Livelihood
Diversification
Ellis (Chapter 3) examines the reasons why households might diversify
their activities and income sources. The most obvious (but not
necessarily the most illuminating) classification of reasons is the
distinction between necessity
and choice (forced or
involuntary versus desired or voluntary). Although attractive - choice
implies that at least the basic necessities of survival have been
achieved - the distinction can be superficial. As Ellis points
out, many potentially desirable options from a household's point of
view may be prevented or heavily constrained by social relations
or institutions or organisations.
Ellis suggests that the distinction between Household Strategies and Trends / Processes may be more
useful: the strategies are the responses to the conditions generated
through the trends and processes. The simple farm household economic
model illustrates the point:
- Households will seek diversified livings if the returns to
off-farm or non-farm labour are higher than those which can be made on
the farm.
- Hence, if farm returns improve (better yielding varieties, higher
prices), diversification will be less.
- Similarly, if off-farm or non-farm opportunities are not
available or are socially restricted (e.g. gender), there will be
limited diversification.
- In addition, if opportunities to use off-farm or non-farm incomes
are limited (lack of markets or of goods and services, or high prices
of these), then diversification will be limited.
- Different risks associated with each potential income stream will
also affect the extent of diversification.
Ellis (Chapter 3) identifies six major Trends and Processes which are
likely to be critical in determining the extent of
diversification responses (all of which will be conditioned by the
asset base, especially Social Capital):
Trends
& Processes
|
Responses
|
Seasonality: continuous consumption needs
mismatched with uneven income flows
|
Occupations change with seasons,
depending on labour markets and risks; seasonal migration - especially
important in droughts as family sizes are reduced; food (or cash)
stocks required to "fund" heavy labour use during planting or harvest.
|
Risk: variability in income streams for
different occupations and activities - behaviours in response to anticipated variability ex ante
|
Diversify income sources, so
that peaks in one stream coincide with troughs in others (find
activities whose riskiness depends on different factors). The higher
the risk of one stream, the greater the incentive to find contingency
or fall-back occupations and activities, which may be other crops or
farm activities.
|
Coping Behaviours:
how households deal with un-anticipated
disasters or difficulties after
they have happened ex post. Often
associated with ideas of vulnerability
(to shocks) and resilience
(ability to cope) and sensitivity
(extent of effect of shock).
|
Often a consumption management
strategy, rather than an income management strategy - survival
strategies (through necessity rather than choice), often
exhibiting a progression from distress actions (seeking alternative
incomes, migration etc.) through to crisis actions (killing livestock,
realising assets for consumption).
Adaptation: may be
positive or negative (forced, involuntary; irreversible; reduces
security and asset status). - retreat to subsistence farming
|
Labour Markets:
modified by Social Rules and Institutions, and the extent of compatible
Human Capital assets.
|
Lack of well-established and
reliable local markets and strong local economies leads to temporary
(or permanent) migration, and the importance of remittances.
Local markets and labour opportunities may suffer supervision and moral hazard problems - incentive
compatibilities can be problematic; as can job search and travel time
and effort -> small farms more suitable than large farms?
Migration:
seasonal; temporary (circular, non domiciliary); permanent
(rural-urban); international. Individual choice or family
(household)
contracts? Remittance income often valuable in risk terms, even if not
actual level. Push
and pull factors
identified as reasons.
|
Credit Markets:
The lack of these, their unreliability and their costs often advanced
as major reasons for lack of development.
|
May be a reflection, rather than
cause, of low asset status (lack of collateral) and low incomes (lack
of ability to service loans), and associated lack of institutions,
organisations and associated social capital.
Diversification of income sources can be a substitute for lack of
working capital sources.
|
Asset Strategies:
investing for the future.
|
Diversification to improve asset
status, but many assets depend on public infrastructure (roads and
communications) and institutions.
|
2.
A PERSONAL VIEW
A The Essential Logic
Human systems are living systems - they follow a Darwinian
logic - making the best possible use of available resources
according
to the socio-economic and political pressures ruling at the time (which
determine the best fit of allocation of scarce resources to
best
uses), and making use of such technologies and techniques as are
available,
tried, tested and trusted. The best-fitted systems and organisms
(families, clans, firms, organisations etc.) grow better and replicate
faster than those
which do not fit.
In such systems, specialisation of function and trade
between entities
(people, communities, localities, regions, sectors
and states) are necessary characteristics.
In this sense, Economics is very largely simply a
re-specification
of the principles of darwinian evolution and the survival of the fittest
- not, notice, the winner taking all, nor, by and large, domination by
single species (except in the most malign, sparse and poor
environments).
Economic development, then, should lead to richer environments and
greater
diversity. How does this happen in evolutionary systems?
The development process happens as a result of
experiments
and innovations - new ways of doing things, both technical and
institutional
(the human rules and habits governing how we do things and for what
purpose).
Natural development is the result of historical accidents - most of
which
fail, and only a few succeed - and are then able to replicate, breed,
multiply
and succeed. Arguably, most human (socio-economic) development
has
also happened by accident - most favourable innovations surviving and
replicating
while less favourable developments tend not to be able to compete and
hence die out.
As with natural ecologies, development status is necessarily context
and circumstance specific (where you are and where you come from
matter).
The richer the habitats (the more resources) the more extensive and
diverse
will be the ecologies (economies), but these will differ from one
another
if they are isolated - the Galapagos and Australasia for example,
though
available niches will tend to be filled with similar organisms in the
sense
of filling the same place and role in the food chains and cycles.
Isolated ecologies, though, tend to be vulnerable to invasion and
invasive
species, which are better fitted to the environment than the natives.
Furthermore, naturally developing ecologies tend to develop their
own
resource base - making soil from rock etc. - via re-cycling
their
food stuffs - the socio-economic counterparts being the circular flow
of
income and the flows of information and knowledge, habits and
rules.
In this sense, living systems accumulate resources and capacities.
But human systems are different from natural systems - human
systems
self-select, whereas natural systems are naturally
selected. Humans think they can make the rules about who lives
and
who dies, who prospers and who does not. It is the self-selection
systems
which are critical in human development processes - what signals,
incentives
and penalties are attached to certain forms of behaviour and activity?
The market system provides one set of incentives and
penalties
- through explicit or implicit prices on goods, services and
factors
of production, and thus on the returns and incomes to be made from
various
activities and the choices made about what to consume and how much to
save.
This system - the competitive market place - operates largely according
to natural principles - survival, prosperity and replication of the
fittest
- leading to obvious inequality, but limited accumulation of power over
the natural selection process - the large are necessarily most
vulnerable
to disruption of their food chains, and are frequently indicator
species
- a signal of the richness and diversity of the whole surrounding
ecology.
However, the market system has evolved into capitalism, which differs
from the survival of the fittest by establishing the ability to trade ownership of assets
and resources between people. Because assets can be traded (exchanged),
accumulation of assets amongst a few becomes possible, and the system
can become the survival of the richest rather than the fittest.
Market power (the ability of producers to dictate what and for whom)
is
regarded as a market failure, which needs social governance (typically
formal government) to offset and overcome. Similarly, the power of the
rich over the poor can onlybe sustained if the poor remain sufficiently
content or cowered to put up with it. If not, they rebel and
revolt - they develop a new governance system. Our governance
systems - from local habits and customs to
formal
government rules and regulations - provide the other major set of
incentives
and penalties - which does admit of power, and the fundamental exercise
of self-selection rather than natural selection. Power, then, is
the ability to choose and the associated ability to persuade or require
others to make particular choices.
The implication is that development is a reflection of the interaction
of all these constituent parts and mechanisms - no one part is
inherently
more or less important than ay other - it is fit which counts, what
will
fit with what in any particular context and circumstance? If we
change
the context and circumstance, we will get a different (not necessarily
better or worse) development pattern. If we change one part (such
as substituting democratic control for autocratic control) this will
have
different consequences depending on what other systems we have in place
and what resource base we have.
Trade and specialisation (market systems) naturally evolve in human
systems through and from barter as the most efficient and effective
ways
of making the best use of available resources. All other forms of
human interaction associated with doing things will tend to involve
higher
transactions costs (be less efficient or effective) except in special
circumstances,
such as small and highly cohesive communities and families (the human
organisation
equivalent of single organism) - when different organisations or
communities (different species) compete for use of the same resources,
then the market system - natural selection - tends to take over as the
most efficient form of transaction/transformation. Ecologies do
this
through the transmission and transformation of food and energy (the
various
biological and bio-physical cycles), while economies do it through
economic
cycles, like the circular flow of income and the interactions between
markets, especially through information and communication (as necessary
parts of trade).
However, markets and natural selection require that the final
arbiter
of who lives and dies is external, as a given outside determinant
(g.o.d.)
- in the natural selection case, as the laws of bio-physics governing
the
nature of the transactions and transformations of food and energy, and
the possibilities for improvement or adjustment/adaptation of practice
within these laws. In the human case, governance takes over from
the bio-physical laws as the final arbiter. Markets exist and are
allowed to thrive only insofar as their societies will let them and
encourage
them. Hence, it is these governance systems (our habits and rules
of social organisation - called institutions by North) which are the
key
elements of the development process.
Prudent and sensible macroeconomic management (requiring stable and
legitimate (legitimised) government) is generally a necessary
precursor,
as are the major elements of a functioning market system.
However,
neither of these is sufficient to ensure sensible development, and both
could, perhaps, be overcome by socio-political governance of the
'right'
type - i.e. the type which best fits existing contexts and
circumstances.
B Some Implications
- Development Processes are necessarily unique to the time
and
space
within which they happen - the development experience of, e.g. western
europe or north america, will be different from each other and will
almost
certainly not be replicated by other countries development trajectories
or opportunities. For example, the major development phase of the
industrial revolution (driven by an extraordinary harnessing of fossil
fuels and minerals to the engine of engineering innovation, and more
lately
production line manufacturing and processing) is unlikely to be
repeated
in quite the same way now - it has happened already and when and as it
happens again (as in India, for instance) it will happen
differently.
Similarly, the extraordinary development of North America cannot happen
again (as the exploitation of a territory treated as virgin by groups
of
refugees and expatriates from elsewhere).
- The Processes are probably much more important than the structures
- who builds and runs a dam, for what purposes and according to whose
priorities,
and who gets the rewards, is more important than the dam itself -
similarly with socio-economic organisations such as private companies,
banks etc. One thing is clear- if people can make a living at it,
it has a very good chance of happening - example
- But, mostly our present theories and understandings have
to do
with
structures rather than processes - so our abilities to analyse and
understand
development is likely to be confused and confusing. Hence -
development
remains a very significant challenge to social sciences and
practitioners.
- Just possibly, notions more akin to husbandry, cultivation,
selective
breeding,
nurture etc. are more useful to understanding development than much of
our more conventional social science tool kits (from whatever
discipline). Culture,
not just agriculture, is a key?
- But, if so, who governs the cultivators? The answer must be
that
future history will govern present cultivators - those trying to do the
development. If it works and fits, it will perpetuate and the
future
history will judge and govern the present developers. If it
doesn't
work, then the present developers will not find their work and ideas
replicated.
Problem - this is small comfort to those who are required (through no
available
alternatives) to suffer the present development experiments.
- The only alternative is to develop a common framework
within
which
the development processes can be commonly understood and discussed -
which
we do not have at present. Without this, we cannot hope to avoid
the stupid mistakes by talking about them and thinking about them
before
we commit to them.
Which is why I am trying (off and on, or even most of the time) to
develop
an outline logic of what such a common framework might look like -
which
would allow us to trade and exchange ideas and concepts and
perspectives,
and thus learn both from each other, and also from the very process of
trade in ideas. The present state of this ridiculously ambitious
research agenda is outlined on my research
web-site. For the present, the sustainable livelihoods framework,
as an increasingly widely used tool for understanding and promoting
sustainable development, seems to fit.
C. Some other evidence?
Jared Diamond: Guns, Germs and
Steel, a short history of everybody
for the last 13,000 years., Vintage, London, 1998, (Robinson
Student Texts Collection, 303.4 DIA) addresses the
question
of why some societies (especially the north west), seem to have made
different
progress than other societies, which, furthermore, appear to have
become
the dominant societies in the present world. His underlying
rationale
is: "History followed different course for different people because of
differences among people's environments, not because of biological
differences
among people themselves" (p 25). The germ of his argument
(thesis,
story), which is a good read, is as follows:
- The proximate causes of European expansion into (especially) the
Americas
appear to be:
- European germs wiping out native peoples
- Horses (unknown in South America)
- Literacy (enabling habits, conventions and institutions to be
replicated
between generations with more certainty)
- Political organisation - collective action
- Technology - especially guns
- Ultimate Causes of these 'advantages'?
- Food production and cultivation (the progression from
hunter-gatherer
to farmer) - depended on the availability of cultivable and
domesticable
plants and animals - only locally available grasses (cereals) and
domesticable
animals, all to be found in central europe but not, typically,
elsewhere.
- which could spread only in specific directions, governed by the
early
geography of the planet
- and which allowed for the development of dense populations,
which
generated diseases
particularly adapted to such populations, and thus encouraged the
adaptations of resistance to these diseases in the indigenous
populations
- and which also generated the advantages of writing - to
pass on
the lessons of cultivation and also enable the necessary transactions
between
commercial farmers and the rest of the population (involving money and
contracts).
- and which also allowed for specialisation, including
the
development
of a craftsman and ultimately inventor, entrepreneurial and bureaucracy
(governing and organising) classes -> technology & political
organisation
(and necessary investment)
- aided and abetted by relative abundance of raw materials (coal
and
iron).
- [and the subsequent evolution of capital markets]
Back to top
Back to SLFA Index
Comments or suggestions
to DRH