AEF811:  WORLD MARKETS AND THE WTO

This page serves to highlight and signpost the essential componants of the world markets and WTO topic.  Each section provides links to further detail on the topic or issue where appropriate.
  1. Simple Economics of Trade and the Gains from Trade, plus outline reasons for policy
  2. The Partial analysis of trade - and the importance of the concepts of excess supply and excess demand
  3. The WTO & Trade Negotiations:
    1. The Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture
    2. The Current Situation - the Millenium Round
    3. A Guess at the critical issues facing the negotiations

1.    Simple Economics of why Trade (and associated specialisation) is a "Good Thing"

Any society (household, region, nation etc.) can be represented as having a particular productive capacity, given its resources of land, labour, capital and management) such that its production possibilities are shown as the Production Possibility Frontier - concave to the origin, since some resources are better at producing one thing (say M) than another (say G).

Without trade (under conditions of autarchy), this society will choose some particular mix of M and G (say at point A, producing and, necessarily, consuming amounts Am and Ag respectively).  Notice that this choice, whatever it is, necessarily requires that the rate at which these two goods can be exchanged (both on the supply (ppf) side and the demand side of the local domestic market) will be equal to the Autarchy Price Ratio.  Supply price (the slope of the ppf) is equal to the demand price (given by the choice exercised by the society as to which mix of goods to consume).  The market is in balance, and, providing that the ppf and the choices exercised by society include all public goods and externalities), the efficient price.  Supply curves - the price at which succesive amounts of any one good can be produced - necessarily slope upwards for this reason.  (Question -  do demand curves necessarily slope downwards, and does it matter if they don't?).

Trade will only occur if this society meets and negotiates with some different society (with different ppf, and/or different social valuations on the possible products).  If all societies are exactly the same, then trade will neither happen nor be sensible.  Trade relies on differences - so the "level playing field" notion can be very misleading.

When trade happens, a new and different price ratio will be established - the Trade Price Ratio.  This society can now choose a new combination of goods to consume, not totally restricted by its own ppf - it can specialise in the production of the good which is more valuable in trade (good M in this case), and export some of this good (amount Pm(t) less Am) in return for imports of G (amount Cg(t) less Pg(t)).  Amount Ex of M buys amount Im of G on the 'world' market.  So now our society is consuming at point Tc (chosen arbitrarily here to be the same amount of M as before, but more G - unambigously better off.  By how much?

By the value of the additional G consumed, valued at the pre-trade price ratio given by the autarchic price ratio.  Or, by the increased income generated by trade - the value of the exports valued at the trade price ratio.  The two values are not identical - they are measured at different price relatives (real prices).  Which is the most relevant depends on the reasons we need the measurement - but the difference does not invalidate the general principle - people are better off if they specialise and trade.  Otherwise, we wouldn't do it.  And we do, all the time.  Very very few of us, if any, really choose to be totally self-sufficient - life is too short and too miserable if we do.

Restriction of trade or distortion of trading price ratios necessarily makes our society worse off than it otherwise could be.  Q.E.D.

1.b    Why Policy?  Given this argument and logic, why do governments interfere with trade?  Some of the more important answers are as follows:

  1. Exploitation of the gains from trade can clearly involve substantial adjustment - moves from A to Tp on the diagram involve restructuring the economy.  Producers of G in this illustration will loose from trade, while producers of M will gain.  Losing prooducers will typically try and defend their historic positions and ask governments to interfere and protect their markets by regulating or preventing competitive imports.
  2. Consumption depends on consumers command over resources - this is the way they obtain their incomes.  But their commoand over resources depends on historical accident, and the good luck to be in the right placee at the right time.  These capricious accidents are not always regarded as just or equitable, and people demand that their governments redistribute income or resources to satisfy distributional objectives - assisting the less well off at the expense of the better off.  In particular, it is frequently judged that people should have more or less free access to at least basic education and health (and even a secure food supply) if not to some cultural facilties and experience, regardless of their income or wealth.  Therefore, it is often assumed that government should provide these merit goods and services free at the point of use.
  3. Markets sometimes fail:  key failures are externalities (by-products of either production or consumption which are uncompensated or unrewarded, e.g pollution, congestion, or diverse wildlife generated by traditional farming) and public goods - which are non-rival in consumption (my enjoyment does not detract from your enjoyment) and which are non-excludable (I cannot prevent you from enjoying or using them) - eg national defence, pretty landscapes.  Governments can (and should?) take steps to correct these market failures.
  4. Markets do not always work smoothly or efficiently - since they need to take account of transactions and negotiations costs, and associated uncertainties (which cost time, effort and resources).  Provision of these services, or assistance with them, is frequently regarded as the job of government.
For more on the reasons for public policies, see Policy Primer, especially pages 1; and pages 5 - 7 (the rest of this primer is about the assumptions and theory underlyuing economic analysis of policy, which is only relevant to students with a primary interest in the economics of policy.  We can develop some of these ideas and explore the implications more fully if there is sufficient demand from the class - contact me if you are interested.


 

2.    World Market as an excess-demand (or excess-supply) curve:  The key concepts (see here for a fuller explanation of these points)


3.    The WTO & Trade Negotiations:  (See here for fuller account of the history of the WTO)

a)    URAA - the first attempt to bring Agricultual Trade into the GATT. The structure of the agreement is identified in the following Table (from IATRC, 1994)
RULES  LIBERALISATION  SAFEGUARDS, 
ACCOMMODATIONS 
&GUARANTEES
MARKET ACCESS Change non-tariff trade measures to tariffs

Establish tariff quotas

Bind all tariffs 

reduce existing & new tariffs by 36% on average over 6 years

reduce tariffs for each item by at least 15%

Guaranteed access opportunities to exporters through tariff rate quotas (Min of 5% of domestic markets by end of 6 yrs.)

Special safeguards for importers

EXPORT COMPETITION Defined limits on existing export subsidies

No new export subsidies

Reduce expenditure by 36% over 6 year

Reduce volume by 21% over 6 years

Adherence to food aid rules

Negotiate later on export credits

DOMESTIC SUBSIDIES  "Green Box" defined for allowable subsidies Aggregate Measure of Support (including all trade-distorting measures) to be reduced by 20% over 6 years Many LDC subsidies exempted

payments under "blue box" production limiting programmes exempted

(Note:  De-Minimis provisions - generally that support and protection at levels of less than 5% can be ignored - i.e not bothered with by the international rules and procedures)

b.    "The WTO is a rules-based, member-driven organization ó all decisions are made by the member governments, and the rules are the outcome of negotiations among members."  - It is the authority which implements the agreements on rules and procedures already agreed by the member states - which is a definite advance on the GATT, where each ruling and decision was subject to confirmation by a vote amongst the signatories.


c.    Current Situation: (from WTO Web Page)
Negotiations on agriculture began in early 2000, under Article 20 of the WTO Agriculture Agreement. By November 2001 and the Doha Ministerial Conference, 121 governments had submitted a large number of negotiating proposals.

These negotiations will continue, but now with the mandate given by the Doha Declaration, which also includes a series of deadlines. The declaration builds on the work already undertaken, confirms and elaborates the objectives, and sets a timetable. Agriculture is now part of the single undertaking in which virtually all the linked negotiations are to end by 1 January 2005.

The single undertaking also includes negotiations under the headings of:

The declaration reconfirms the long-term objective already agreed in the present WTO Agreement: to establish a fair and market-oriented trading system through a programme of fundamental reform. The programme encompasses strengthened rules, and specific commitments on government support and protection for agriculture. The purpose is to correct and prevent restrictions and distortions in world agricultural markets.

Without prejudging the outcome, member governments commit themselves to comprehensive negotiations aimed at:

The declaration makes special and differential treatment for developing countries integral throughout the negotiations, both in countriesí new commitments and in any relevant new or revised rules and disciplines. It says the outcome should be effective in practice and should enable developing countries meet their needs, in particular in food security and rural development.
The ministers also take note of the non-trade concerns (such as environmental protection, food security, rural development, etc) reflected in the negotiating proposals already submitted. They confirm that the negotiations will take these into account, as provided for in the Agriculture Agreement.

Key dates
Start: early 2000
Formulas and other ěmodalitiesî for countriesí commitments: by 31 March 2003
Countriesí comprehensive draft commitments: by 5th Ministerial Conference, 2003 (in Mexico)
Stock taking: 5th Ministerial Conference, 2003 (in Mexico)
Deadline: by 1 January 2005, part of single undertaking.


d.    DRH Guess at key or pivotal focus of the current agricultural negotiations:  The extent to which international agreements can be allowed to restrict the scope of domestic policies, or conversely, the extent to which domestic policies can be allowed to damage international markets and trade opportunities.  This will probably materialise under four major issues:

In short - the closer the WTO gets to a liberal (largely free) trade position, the more its rules and procedures (the evidence and argument it will accept in determining the application of the rules) will be questioned and potentially deemed illegitimate by the electorates of the member governments.  Interesting times - which is a Chinese curse rather than a blessing.

Back to AEF811 index