AEF811: MACROECONOMICS:  THE BASICS

Note: to use as a dictionary of terms - use "find" in your browser menu bar.

Managing in and with markets requires some knowledge of the basic Macroeconomic relationships - concerning interest rates, income growth rates, exchange rates, unemployment rates etc.  These notes are a very brief outline of the major elements of Macroeconomics.  For those who would like a more extended treatment, see any introductory textbook of economics, or try my first year undergraduate macro economics course notes.

CONTENTS: Comments, questions and suggestions??
  1. The Link between Microeconomics and Macroeconomics - General Equilibrium in all markets
  2. Macroeconomic Basics - the Circular Flow of Income (CFoI), with Government and Fiscal Policy
  3. Macroeconomics of Money Money Markets, Financial Markets and Capital Markets - and Monetary Policy
  4. Macroeconomics of Money with the CFoI( IS/LM): Monetary and Fiscal Policy to achieve Macroeconomic equilibrium (low Unemployment and low Inflation)
  5. Macroeconomics of International Trade - The Forex market
  6. MacroEconomic Management:

1.    The Link between Microeconomics and Macroeconomics - General Equilibrium in all markets and Value Added

The Market system works through specialisation and trade:  People, communities, regions and countries are better off specialising in production and trading the products with neighbours than they would be if they tried to be completely self-sufficient.  If this were not the case, markets would not exist.
Specialisation and Trade relies on people and their businesses exploiting their comparative advantage - specialising their productive activities in those areas and products for which they are best able, relative to all the other things which they might do instead.  Their opportunity costs should then be less than the returns they can earn doing their present things, and they will make a positive return as a consequence.

The general picture of interacting markets - the circular flow of income:

[Note:  profits in the everyday sense are, typically, just the returns to capital - the earnings of the firms which are left after all other legitimate costs (including labour and management costs) have been deducted.  For self-employed family businesses, taxable profits will include the returns to the owners own labour and management, as well as returns to the owners land and capital, less allowable expenses in servicing mortgages, loans and debts.]

The UK food chain illustrates the outcome of this circular flow of income.
Agricultural and Food Chain, UK, 2000
Farms produce £15.3 bn. of output, of which £8.7bn. is spent on purchased inputs, leaving £6.6bn. as the gross product (gross margin) or returns to the factors of production (land, labour, management and capital).

Measurement Issues: Back to Contents.
 


2.    Macroeconomic Basics - the Circular Flow of Income (CFoI)

Simplify the whole economy as an interaction between Consumers (households), Producers (firms), and Government.  NOTE:  This is a circular flow of INCOME (and spending) - although measured and identified in money terms, it is the livings (income and spending) - the real purchasing power of the money - which is important here.  Always refer to the flow as an INCOME flow and not a flow of money.
Notice, too, that Income (GDP) is typically related to the level of employment and unemployment - the lower the level of GDP relative to its trend, see below, the higher the level of unemployment.
NOTE:  Necessary Accounting equality (Total Expenditure = Income) over any one period (one year)  does not necessarily imply equilibrium.  If Expenditure is growing, then so too will income - and both will be larger in the next period.  If income is falling, then spending will also fall, and both will be smaller next period.

Distinguish between

Equilibrium Process of the CFoI. Fiscal Policy as a stabiliser of economic cycles: Capacity Limits: Money and CFoI (and Inflation) Back to Contents.


3.    Macroeconomics of Money

Money is used both as a medium of exchange for transactions (active bank balances) and also as a store of wealth (idle bank balanes).
Demand for and Supply of Money:  The price of money is the interest rate

Financial Markets  ->  the rate of interest

  1. Rate of Interest = price of money:- the cost of getting more of it from banks etc., or the opportunity cost of saving (= storing income as wealth, by owning assets, from savings accounts (loans to other people and businesses) up to land, buildings, and old master paintings)
  2. Assets differ in terms of:
  3. The Rate of Return earned by any asset is fundamentally related to the ratio of the current capital value of the asset (its price for outright purchase now) to its annual return (i).  In general, Present Value of an asset = discounted sum of all future returns (annual payments or Future Values), where the discount rate is the rate of interest.
  4. Rates of Return differ because:
  5. In general: the rate of return on any asset  i = r + u + p, where i is the asset's rate of return in current or nominal terms: r is the real interest rate (opportunity cost of money); u is the risk premium for this asset; p is the expected rate of inflation.  [Note:  physical assets also depreciate (wear out and become obsolete), so their value diminishes over time - so their rate of return has to include an allowance for depreciation (d).]
All these factors affect different assets and their rates of return (or interest rates) differently.  The financial markets are where these differences are traded off with and against each other.  So long as these markets are competitive (no one person or business can affect or partially control the supplies or demands for financial and physical assets), then all these different interest rates will end up being closely and reliably related to each other in an inter-related constellation of interest rates.  If one asset shows exceptional returns relative to the others on offer in these markets, then investors will flock towards the premium asset and away from the others.  The price paid for the premium asset will rise relative to the rest, and the return to be earned as a percentage of the buying (aquisition) price will fall.  The result will be that the premium return (interest rate) disappears and comes back into line with the other rates, given its risk and inflation characteristics.  Conclusion:  a single interest rate is sufficient to represent all the different interest rates exhibited in competitive financial markets, which underly the Money market above.

Capital Markets:

The rate of interest also influences Savings and Investment - the balance in the capital market for loanable (investment) funds
Notice: If the interest rate (set in the money market) results in I > S, then there will be a tendency for the level of National Income (Y) to grow - increasing savings (shifting this ceteris paribusSavings supply curve to the right as incomes increase) to match the additional investment.  However, increasing Y might also increase Imports and Taxes - so that the imbalance between savings and investment might persist - offset by imbalances between G and T, and between IM and X.
 

Back to Contents.


4.    Macroeconomics of Money with the CFoI( IS/LM)

Management of the Macroeconomy depends on achieving an appropriate balance between the markets for goods and services (as represented by the CFoI) and the money markets (as above.
It therefore depends on achieving an appropriate balance between the two major levers of macroeconomic management: Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy.
The Key variables in this balance are the level of national income (Y) and the rate of interest (r) - charted on the IS/LM diagram:

The IS curve refers to the equilibrium levels of National Income in the markets for goods and services (CFoI).  Here, higher rates of interest are associated with lower levels of spending (higher savings, lower investment, lower levels of consumption) - so the IS curve slopes downwards. Note the direction of causation:  setting the interest rate determines savings (withdrawals) and investment (injections), which then determines the equilibrium level of national income.
The LM curve refers to the equilibrium in the Money Markets - given a fixed money supply. Here, higher levels of national income lead to greater demand for money (for transactions), and hence higher rates of interest (given a fixed money supply)- so the LM curve slopes upwards. Note the direction of causation (opposite from IS curve) - incomes drive the demand for money, which then sets the interest rate if the supply of money is fixed (or sets the supply of money if the interest rate is fixed)
Fiscal Policy affects the IS curve - expansionary (increase G, reduce T) shifts IS right, and vice versa.
Monetary Policy affects the LM curve - expansionary (increasing Ms, reducing interest rates) shifts LM right, and vice versa.
The relative effectiveness of Monetary and Fiscal Policies in influencing Y (and thus employment) depends, therefore, on the slopes of the IS and LM curves.
The steeper the LM curve, the greater the "crowding out" effect of government spending - G increases increase interest rates which reduce (crowd out) private spending.
Inflation effects - If equilibrium Y* is greater than the full capacity of the economy - there will be pressure on prices - leading to inflation.  Inflation reduces the value of the fixed Money Supply, shifting LM left, raising interest rates and reducing Y* back towards its full capacity level.
BoE MPC raising interest rates to limit inflation is the practical counterpart of this effect - by rasing interest rates, the MPC effectively holds the Money Supply constant in the face of increasing demand.
 

Back to Contents.


5.    Macroeconomics of International Trade

What, if anything, balances Imports with Exports in the CFoI?   The Foreign Exchange (Forex) market  -  where people and businesses trade one currency for another. The 1996 UK situation:
DemandCeteris paribus, exports and capital inflows will be greater the lower the exchange rate - demand curve slopes downwards.
Supply : ceteris paribus, will be greater the higher is the exchange rate - the supply curve slopes upwards.
Equilibrium exchange rate balances exports plus capital inflows with imports plus capital outflows.
Exchange rate managed by BoE control of Forex reserves, and also through borrowing (repaying) loans from foreign banks.
Dforex and Sforex are also affected by Incomes (Y) and Interest rates Monetary Policy more powerful under floating exchange rates than fixed:  Expansionary monetary policy: Purchasing Power Parity Theory of exchange rates - freely floating (unmanaged) exchange rates will adjust in response to trade-driven demands and supplies of currencies so that (or until) the prices of the same goods are the same in all countries.  The  prices of an identical 'basket' of goods and services should be the same in all countries - freely floating exchange rates will adjust to ensure that this is the case - the exchange rates which would produce this result are known as the 'purchasing power parity' rates (ppp rates).

This theory relies simply on the pursuit of profitable trading opportunities - there are at least some people or firms who will take advantage of the opportunities to buy cheap and sell dear and make a profit. If they can, they will, and will go on doing so until the prices (and exchange rates) adjust to remove the profitable opportunities. This pursuit of trading profit is also known as arbitrage - from the same root as arbitrate - to arbitrate between prices on the basis of profit opportunities. It is this arbitrage which ensures, in this simple 'model' or view of the world, the adjustment of prices and exchange rates to make prices the same in all countries - it is only then that arbitrage opportunities are eliminated.
The Economist magazine regularly publishes (at least once a year) its Big Mac index of exchange rates based on this principle - what would the exchange rate have to be to make the price of a Big Mac the same? The answer is a close approximation to the PPP rate between the two countries.
Back to Contents.


6.    MacroEconomic Management: 

6.1.    The Basics

Economies tend to cycle between booms and recessions: Counter-cyclical macro-management:  (trying to actively predict and counter-act these cyclical tendencies)  Problematic because: Active counter-cyclical management tended to exacerbate rather than ameliorate economic cycles  - boom/bust economies.  Prefered option now: Inflationary (boom) situation:

Deflationary (recession) situation:

6.2    Which is more effective?  Fiscal or Monetary Policy?

Experiments with the IS/LM model should clearly show that the effectiveness of Fiscal and Monetary Policies in governing (managing) the circular flow of income depend on the slopes of the IS and LM curves.

Slopes of the IS and LM Curves:

The IS curve depends on the sensitivity (responsiveness) of aggregate demand to changes in the rate of interest. It will be flatter the more responsive aggregate demand (the expenditure loop of the CFoI) is to changes in the interest rate. On the other hand, if aggregate demand (consumption plus investment) mostly depend on the current state of the economy and feelings or expectations about future incomes and spending (growth), then interest rates may be relatively unimportant in determining aggregate demand, and the IS curve will be steep.

The LM curve depends on the sensitivity (responsiveness) of money demand to income - the more responsive the demand for money is to income changes, the steeper is the LM curve. It is also the case that the more responsive the demand for money is to interest rates, (the more elastic the demand for money w.r.t interest rates) the flatter is the LM curve.

Scenario 1 - the classic Depression

This is the story (approximately) for the Great Depression, and much of the 50s and early 60s - power to Fiscal Policy and Money does not matter much. If you want to get out of a 1930s type depression, then the Keynesian solution of demand management works- kick start the depressed economy through increased government spending over and above taxation receipts.

Scenario 2 - the more modern economy

These developments during the seventies may well have made the economy more sensitive to monetary management and correspondingly less sensitive to fiscal policy.  Power shifts towards Monetary Policy and away from Fiscal Policy.

Effect of inflation: Notice, if there is inflation in the economy, then this will reduce the value of money in terms of its purchasing power, which will mean that more money is required to finance any given level of transactions or level of real national income. This means that the supply of money in real terms is reduced, shifting the LM curve to the left, increasing interest rates and reducing the level of national income.

Inflation will thus tend to reduce income and increase unemployment - so long as monetary policy is kept reasonably tight. Overheating (expanding) the economy will, in these conditions, generate stagflation (both inflation and increased unemployment) - the typical economic condition in the UK during the 1970s.

6.3    Inclusion of Forex Market:

As the economy expands, and national income grows, there is a tendency for imports to expand faster than exports, and for the Balance of Trade to move into deficit. This would lead to a depreciation of the exchange rate. To maintain the exchange rate, the monetary authorities could (should?) increase interest rates to encourage capital inflows and discourage capital outflows on the capital account of the Balance of Payments, thus offsetting the current account deficit.
Thus we may also include an exchange rate equilibrium condition on the IS/LM diagram, which shows this necessary relationship to keep exchange rates constant. This is drawn in the following diagram as the B/C curve - showing an equilibrium exchange rate at some fixed rate achieved through the balance of the Balance of Trade and the Capital account of the Balance of Payments.

Thus, any point to the left of the BC curve indicates a Balance of Payments surplus at that level of Y and r, and an appreciating currency under a floating exchange rate regime. Any point to the right of the BC curve indicates a balance of payments deficit and a depreciating currency. As the currency depreciates, so BC shifts rightwards. As the exchange rate appreciates, so BC shifts left.

This diagram also includes the 'target' of full employment or full capacity National Income (Y*). The implication is that this economy as pictured is not yet at equilibrium at full employment - nor is there yet a consistent equilibrium at any level of national income at which all three major markets (goods, money and forex) will be at equilibrium. It needs managing!  One obvious management tool is to allow the exchange rate to depreciate - shifting the B/C curve to the right.

The market mechanism (under floating exchange rates) can be expected to shift the BC curve to the right, as the currency depreciates towards the money/goods equilibrium (intersection of the IS and LM curves). As it does so, there may be some inflation triggered by the depreciation, which would shift the LM curve to the left, raising interest rates. But this new equilibrium would not be at full employment - it would lie to the left of Y*. The economy would now have to rely on one of two major responses:

Economies might not adapt and adjust themselves very quickly - so this economy could stay stuck in an under-employed condition for some time. So there is a strong temptation for governments to take the proactive line and expand the economy with either fiscal or monetary policy or both. The problem is that governments often get this wrong and over-shoot - so generating inflation as the 'natural' equilibria meet to the right of Y*.


Back to Macro Contents.
Back to AEF811 Index.