ACE2006:  Sustainability


A.    What is sustainability?

A1    The Laws of thermodynamics (which apply to ALL CLOSED SYSTEMS - with no external inputs) underpin economic (and all other) systems. The first two laws are:
  1. Materials Balance Princple: Neither matter nor energy can be created or destroyed: total mass-energy is fixed:  all apparent changes are conversions of one form into others. So, the more matter and energy an economy (people) uses, the more natural resource depletion and waste it will generate.
  2. The Entropy Principle: where entropy is a measure of disorder. In a closed system, the use of mass-energy results in a one way flow from low entropy resources (mass-energy) to high entropy resources, from order to disorder. Perpetual motion is impossible - use of energy leads to dissipation of energy into unusable forms (disorder), all we can do is release order, and generate disorder. All closed systems tend to run down and dissipate to disorder, towards maximum entropy. NO CLOSED SYSTEM IS ULTIMATELY SUSTAINABLE. (Though the earth is not closed - it continually receives energy from the sun - the solar system is (for practical purposes), closed, and the sun is runnning down.) So, any discussion of sustainability has to recognise that sustainability is a relative, not absolute concept. Are some processes and activities more or less sustainable than others?
A2.    Ecology: Man is an Animal: whose population will expand to exhaust its local food supplies or life support systems, and then contract (through disease, starvation etc, and, in the case of man alone, wars and conflicts.) to a sustainable level, consistent with the local environment - the Malthusian Principle. The world population has grown from 0.5bn in 1600 to 1.6bn in 1900, to 6 bn. in 2000, and is on track to grow to 9 billion or perhaps more by 2100, with the population explosion coinciding with the advent of the industrial revolution. It has achieved this through making massively more use of the planets resources, and creating more waste as a consequence.  There must be a limit to the human carrying capacity of the planet - but where is this limit? And to what extent does it depend on the state of technology - can technological advance increase the carrying capcity of the planet indefinitely?

A3.    Economic Meaning of Sustainability?

  1. From a simple economist's perspective, sustainability might be taken as the ability to maintain wealth, income, consumption and lifestyles indefinitely.
  2. Since the generation of income and wealth requires the use (exploitation) of both renewable and non-renewable natural and physical resources, and also generates waste and pollution, while at least part of peoples utility and enjoyment derives from appreciation and use of the natural environment and physical character of the planet, sustainability requires that the damage and depletion of the earth's natural resources and environment must be made good somehow, otherwise the processes of income generation will eventually run down. A common way of expressing this requirement is that human activity should be organised as if the human race had a full repairing lease on the planet -> sustainability translates into maintaining the productive capacity of the planet and all its parts: maintaining social, natural, physical and human capital stocks. (see, e.g. Arrow et.al.) - also the UN IHDP's 2012 Inclusive Wealth Report (highlighted by the Economist), which raise the question about  substitutability between different sorts of capital
  3. However, once stated in this way, most people (economists included) might well wish to add that the present distribution of wealth, income, consumption and living standards (quality of life) leaves a lot to be desired, and hence is socially (even morally) unsustainable.  So sustainability should also include the provision to improve welfare, especially of those currently less well-off.
  4. Once again, however, adding this proviso raises several more practical issues -
The general conclusion arising from these considerations is that sustainability is a problem of Market Failure, implying that some form of government intervention (social control) is necessary. Meanwhile, commerce remains skeptical:  a report in the Economist (19.11.04) concludes"The factors that sustain long-term corporate returns are but vaguely understood. Some research suggests a correlation between a company's stance on environmental and social issues and its long-term performance, but none yet shows a causal relationship between them. Until that can be established, investors will be left wondering whether sustainability analysis is more than a mere curiosity." This observation comes at the end of an article about Al Gore's investment management company which will  “integrate rigorous traditional fundamental equity analysis with sustainability research to create a new approach to long-term investing”. Al Gore is teaming up with David Blood (no kidding), previously a chief executive with Goldman Sachs. "Mr Blood was a fund manager who saw a demand for long-term investment to take into account his belief that “social, environmental and geopolitical issues can materially impact a company's ability to sustain returns.” Generation (the name of the Blood and Gore Management company) combines Mr Gore's political savvy with Mr Blood's market instinct."

back to top


B.    Possibilities for Sustainable Land (natural resource) Use?

Bi.   Market Failures:   The critical factors giving rise to Market Failure problems are:

Economics (the market) cannot resolve these problems, except in very special circumstances. Solution requires collective action - governance - the long arm of the law is necessarily attached to the invisible hand of the market, not just to correct for market failure, but also to police the market system (outlaw theft, establish and policy property rights and the laws of contract, and make judgements about relative equity of market outcomes (changing these as seem fit).
 
back to top

Bii.  Problems of Substitution between physical (man-made) and natural capital -> valuation problems again

Sustainability implies at least a constant stock of Capital (both natural (Kn) and physical (man-made, Kk) - and also Human capital in skills and expertise, health and education - Kh, and Social Capital - the social networks, trust relationships, social infrastructure etc (Ks)). In the limit, maintaining a constant stock of natural capital denies the possibility of using any non-renewable resources (coal, oil, natural gas), and also denies the possibility of creating any waste. This strict form of capital sustainability is clearly unworkable (socially unsustainable). Some substitution of man-made capital (wind farms, solar energy panels, water power etc.) for natural capital is necessary for human systems to be termed sustainable. It must be possible to compensate for the loss of natural resources by building up stocks of physical (man-made) capital, otherwise human existence is inherently unsustainable above a very low level (perhaps 0.5 bn. people at subsistence levels of existence).

As stocks of Kn are used up, so they will become scarcer, and thus more valuable (more expensive) - which will both encourage more efficient and economical use of the remaining stock, and encourage the search for and use of alternatives (renewables). We are already seeing some of these natural reactions, as renewable energy sources and energy efficiency measures become more attractive (energy use per £ of GDP is now considerably lower than it was 20 years ago), while we are becoming more concerned about waste disposal as the costs of damage become more obvious and the value of the natural environment increases (less of it per £ of GDP). However, there are 2 major problems with this natural (market) reaction to depletion of natural capital, each of which can compromise the resiliance of market systems to cope with unforseen catastrophes.

  1. uncertainty and technological lags:  Increasing man made capital (Kk) is investing in the future - providing increased capacity to produce and consume at future dates. The future is uncertain.  The more uncertain it is, the lower the incentive to invest, since the probabilities of sufficient returns being generated to repay the investments are lower.  Furthermore, the greater the technical problems of developing alternatives, the longer the lag between recognising the need to invest and the provision of the alternative, and thus the greater the uncertainty and the lower the incentive. Long lead times, and large technological gaps mitigate against simply rational investment decisions - where simply rational means relying on probabilities of outcomes, and treating beneficial outcomes with the same weights as detrimental outcomes. We end up doing too little too late, because we are myopic, except that we don't always.
  2. irreversibility: the simple economic mechanisms tend to assume that economic processes are reversible - if we make mistakes, we can rectify them later. Burning up fossil fuel reserves which took 300 million years to accumulate in 300 years or so is nearly certain to have significant effects on global carbon balances and hence on global climate. But what will be the effects?  We remain uncertain, and we certainly don't know that they will be all bad, though there will be some bad effects.  It is tempting to suppose that we can make good, or at least make do and mend, if we fail to make the appropriate decisions now to limit (or even reduce) carbon emissions - that we can live with our mistakes. But this may turn out to be impossible, or impossibly expensive.  So surely it is more sensible to be cautious now - to adopt the precautionary principle (PP): if we don't know what the effects of certain actions will be, better to avoid them altogether, especially if the possible effects include serious and irreversible damage.  But universal adoption of this principle would eliminate many innovations and many experiments (trials by error), and limit our ability to cope with the future.  In the end, regardless of whether we are economists or not, we take decisions based on guesses about the relative merits - a balance between some guess about the possible benefits versus the possible costs. The PP really only amounts to the identification  of those cases where the possible costs sufficiently exceed the possible benefits as to make the case (decision) daft. Deciding on these cases necesarily involves judgements about relative values of costs and benefits.
Underlying these difficulties are three more fundamental problems: the problem of valuation; the problem of capital; the problem of equity.
 
back to top

Biii.    Identification and Valuation of non-market goods and services

This picture represents the typical problem of commerical farming (especially if subsidised) - that it uses land too intensively to be sustainable.
Intensity of Production (essentially the yields of biomass production per hectare, increased by the application of increased inputs) is measured along the horizontal axis.  The value of the effects of land use is measured on the vertical axis.
The Private (supported) Value of Biomass curve represents the net value (revenues minus all costs except land costs) of the subsidised production of biomass (food and fibre) on this particular hectare of land. It reaches a maximum value at intensity level B.
However, if we were to remove all the subsidies from this production, the net value curve would shift, so as to produce a maximum at intensity level P, the subsidies result in increased intensity of land use (and higher values to land under biomass production).
The remaining curves represent the values of other attributes and characteristics of the land use as intensity changes. (we might add a curve representing sporting rights and benefits as well, which would conflict with some other elements (wildlife) and complement others (other bits of wildlife).
The total social value of land curve is the vertical sum of each of the component curves (removing the subsidy from biomass production).  This total value reaches a maximum at point S.

Is this point (S) the sustainable point of intensity?
Identification of this point requires that the following critical components be identified:

  1. The biophysical consequences of particular land use decisions and practices for the rural environment ? the shapes and locations of the various curves (relationships) in physical terms as intensity is increased (and as production practices are changed).
  2. The behaviour of land managers and users in response to market or policy signals - showing what they will do under different market and policy conditions, and the decisions they will make about land use.
  3. The social valuations of the care (conservation, amenity, recreation and environmental) goods and services themselves - these are typically non-market goods and services, and it is difficult, but not impossible, to estimate peoples willingness to pay for these attributes and services.
Providing that we: Then can we expect market forces and a properly liberalised market to encourage land users to operate at the socially optimal level of intensity and multifunctionality at point S. Then we can regard this land use as sustainable - in the sense that we are properly accounting for the depletion of natural resources used in the production of food and fibre and properly accounting for the other competing and complimentary attributes of this land use.

Notice, however, that this characterisation of the problem is:

  1. Spatially heterogenous - there will be different curves (relationships) for different parcels of land
  2. Temporarly dynamic - these relationships will change through time as new techologies appear and as preferences and social valuations change
  3. Behaviourally heterogeneous - different people, as land onwers and land users, will respond differently to the same market and policy signals.
It is a complex system - which is not formally capable of prediction, but does generate replicating patterns and structures within certain boundary conditions.

See here for an article exploring the implications of this sort of analysis for the appropriate response to quests for a genuinely Multifunctional Agriculture (and previous notes on market failure for reasons why 'pricing' the environment without developing and encouraging actual transactions between beneficiaries and providers (markets) is to put the cart before the horse.)

See the UK National Ecosystem Assessment for a recent attempt to document the variety and value of ecosystem services (points on the various ecosystem curves in the diagram above), supposing that the flow of ecosystem services reflects the capacity of the underlying stock of natural capital to go on delivering these flows.  Documented over the range of UK habitats, including urban and marine, the assessment classifies services as: supporting - the primary functions of soil and associated biota in operating the various bio-physcial flows of energy, water, carbon etc.; regulating -the 'buffering' capacities of the environment in recycling materials and integrating the biosphere (including pollination etc)  provisioning - the supply of food and fibre; and cultural -including the social and recrational value of ecosystems - see the Synthesis of Findings report, p 18 & 25.  The 87 page Synthesis Report makes for some interesting reading, though their valuations are probably inherently suspect, which their scenario analysis might also be questioned on internal consistency grounds, if none other.

back to top

Biv.    Capital: Choices between now and the future (the tyranny of the discount rate)

As if the previous section were not complicated enough, dealing with the heterogenity across space and current behaviours, there is also an all important time dimension. Consider a policy to try and improve the sustainability of a particular land use (choose whatever example you like).  Suppose that we have all the necessary information (referred to above) to identify the costs and benefits of various forms of land use and their effects, and their social values.  This information will be contingent on current preferences, and on current technolgies, and on current capacities (land qualities, buildings, plant and equipment etc. in short on current capital stocks, both man made and natural).

But, we will discover that the biophysical attributes of the environment will be changed according to which land use we choose - the natural capital stock will change through time. So, too will the values people attach to these attributes (both individually and collectively). And, we may imagine, we could do better if we had and used different technologies.  In short, if we did things differently NOW, we would live in a different world in the FUTURE.  But, in order to decide whether or not we should do things differently now, we need to be able to compare the value of the different future conditions we generate with the costs of doing things differently now. Furthermore, the future is a stream of (annual) net benefits or costs, while NOW is a single value.

In simple terms, the value of the future might seem to be simply the sum of all the annual net benefits (NB(t), for each year t in the future) from a particular course of action, which can be compared with the current costs (K) of achieving this net benefit stream, where K is the investment necessary to achieve the future benefit stream.  But, for how long in the future - for ever?  Then any positive net benefit stream, however small the future benefits, will always outweigh the current costs, however large these may be, simply because the sum of an infinite stream is infinite. So this is clearly quite impractical as a guide to decision making.

It is also socially unsustainable - we do not behave as if the future were of exactly equivalent value as the present.

So long as the Capital Markets are working reasonably competitively (which they mostly do), these markets will balance personal time preference rates with the opportunity costs of capital to generate a interest rate - i.

Now we can compare current costs (K) with a future stream of net benefits (NBt).  NB1 - the net benefit we expect to get by the end of year 1, will need to be greater than our cost of securing this benefit now by at least the rate of interest, to make the current investment worthwhile.  So, if we invest £100 now, we need to be sure that our NB1 is at least £105 at a 5% interest rate (= £100 *(1.05)).  In other words, the Present Value (PV) (£100) is equivalent to a Future Value (FV) of £105)

So: FV1 = PV(1+i); or PV = FV1/(1+i).  This is the principle of discounting, where the interest rate is used as a discount rate - discounting the future value to its equivalent present value.  Repeating the same logic for year 2 gives FV2 = [PV(1+i)](1+i)] = PV(1+i2), so for year 2, PV = FV2/(1+i2), and so on as t increases.

The further into the future, the lower is the present value of the future benefit. This discounting of the future is even more severe if there is any uncertainty about our future return, since this uncertainty adds a risk premium to the discount rate.  The greater the uncertainty, the higher the risk premium.  Our behaviour is necessarily myopic - we could not make decisions over time unless this were the case.

Most modern mixed economies operate at a base interest rate (excluding inflation) of about 3 to 6%.  Simple arithmetic - the tyranny of discounting - quickly reduces anticipated future benefits to rather low present value at these rates of interest. For instance, £1000 in 30 years time is only worth £167 today, at a 5% discount or interest rate, and is only worth £333 today at a 2% discount rate.  Predecitions of general catastrophy in 50 years time, coupled with a considerable amount of uncertainty surrounding the nature of this catastrophe, does not appear to warrent very large investments NOW.  Try getting people to pay for avoiding them, and see both the logic and the evidence of this.

However, the converse also applies:  to get £1000 in 30 years time, so long as there is no risk or uncertainty, we only have to invest £167 now, at 5%.  At 2% return, we will need to invest £333 now.  A little spent now might generate considerable returns in the future.

back to top

Bv.    Problems of Efficiency versus Equity (choices between us and them) (markets versus democracy)

There is a further complication to the assessment of costs and benefits - the distribution. Who pays the costs and who gets the benefits also matters. The market accords weight to those with the income and wealth - the more £s you have, the greater your votes in the market place for what you want in competition with everyone else.  Thus, those who own the resources get most of the say in what is produced and how, and for whom, and how much.

However, as humane societies, we also worry about caring for the less well off, at least some of the time, and expect our governments (and NGOs) to look after the poor on our behalf.  We might, therefore, be prepared to weight the interests of the poor (the benefits they miay get) rather more highly than the interests of the rich?  Similarly, we may want to count the costs more highly if they are suffered by the poor rather than by the rich.  To do so requires that we use our governments, through democracy, to exercise these social and caring judgements on our behalf.

Does this mean that we should count future generations welfare at a higher level than our own?  Won't they be richer than us, providing our recent history of economic growth can be sustained?  Won't they be cleverer than us?

Does this mean that we should care more about the very poor, who live a long way away from us, than we care about the relatively poor on our own doorstep?

Questions of sustainability also raise these uncomfortable questions, which cannot be resolved through the market place, but need to be resolved through our governments.

back to top


C. Conclusions and lessons learned?

THE PRINCIPLE CONCLUSIONS TO BE DRAWN FROM THESE CONSIDERATIONS CAN BE GROUPED UNDER TWO MAJOR HEADINGS: ECONOMICS AND SYSTEMS THEORY.
 
ECONOMICS: THERE IS NO SUCH THING AS A FREE LUNCH
SYSTEMS THEORY: SUSTAINABILITY IS RELATIVE: 
Treating the natural environment as if it were a free lunch is reckless, and potentially suicidal. The environment, and all its components, have a price. No closed system is absolutely sustainable except in a state of maximum entropy (complete chaos).
The human condition involves making choices. System persistence depends on buffering feedbacks which constrain explosive or implosive tendencies.
Making choices automatically implies a relative valuation of or judgement about outcomes versus inputs. But too much buffering prevents adaptation and response to changing conditions, and lowers resiliance to external (or unforseen) shocks.
There is no such thing as an invaluable asset - there is always a price at which people (as communities) will be willing to seek an alternative. Systems persist if they balance opposing forces and tendencies,  oscillating as a means of preserving these balances.
Valuations are critical, and are an expression of social choices To do so, they require a continual source of energy of some sort. Perpetual motion is impossible in a closed system.
The ways in which social choices are made are thus critical Human systems are no different, in principle, from biophysical systems.
The market is only one, albeit fundamental, way in which society makes choices Living systems (at least) evolve: they mind and respond, and so adapt to seek best fits with their biophysical environments.
The ways in which society learns to live with the natural processes of market transactions are critical to human sustainability. Human systems care and reply, as well as minding and responding, and thus learn (exhibiting Lamarkian adaptations: nurture breeds as well as grows new natures, which in turn replicate and evolve)
Social science is at least as important as natural science in making our systems more sustainable. In fact, if sustainability means sustaining human existence, social science has to be fundamental. Technology and Natural Science is not enough - these are simply tools.  The rules and reasons of use are more fundamentally important. Social Science needs to grow up, and breed a coherence and consistency which is currently lacking - this is the biggest challenge facing the Human race.

Further Reading:  The Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change. In summary (From the Economist, Nov. 2. 2006 - my emphasis added) : "Sir Nicholas has tried to assess the future costs of climate change—drought in Africa, floods in Europe, hurricanes in America, rising sea levels around the world—and has set them against the costs of cutting fossil-fuel usage enough to stabilise carbon-dioxide concentrations in the atmosphere. His answer to the second part of this calculation is fairly uncontroversial. The costs of switching away from carbon should not be huge because of the rise in fossil-fuel prices and the fall in alternative energy prices. Sir Nicholas reckons that the world could stabilise concentrations at a reasonable level at a cost of 1% of GDP by 2050.  Many other economists have looked at the matter, and most agree with Sir Nicholas.

But Sir Nicholas dissents from the general view on the costs of climate change itself. Most economists who  have looked at the matter up to now reckon that, if greenhouse-gas emissions continue on their current  path, the costs of climate change would be between zero (where the benefits of warming to cold countries  balances out the costs) and 3% of global output over the next 100 years. Sir Nicholas thinks they would  be a massive 5-20% over the next century or two: in other words, world output could be up to a fifth  lower, as a result of climate change, than it otherwise would have been.  He justifies these high numbers on two main grounds. First, he says, the earlier estimates were based on  temperature increases of 2-3°C by the end of this century. But the science has moved on. A better understanding of feedback loops in the climate, such as the melting of Arctic ice, which increases the  region's tendency to absorb sunlight and therefore reinforces warming, means that, although 2-3°C remains the likeliest increase, scientists now think that warming of 5-6°C is a real possibility. That would be a massive jump: 5°C is the difference between the temperature now and in the last ice age.

Second, he points out, most economists have fed only the likeliest climate-change scenario into their models and ignored the outlying possibilities of catastrophe. Sir Nicholas has received plenty of support from economists (four Nobel prize-winners have endorsed the report) and a certain amount of criticism. One complaint is that he has selected the most pessimistic research and ignored more conservative work. Richard Tol, a professor at Hamburg University and a big noise in this field, describes the report as “alarmist and incompetent”. Another criticism is that figures on the economic costs of climate change are bound to be nonsense because they are based on a cascade of uncertainties. Nobody knows just how much carbon dioxide the world is going to produce in future. Nobody knows just what it will do to the temperature. Nobody knows just how temperature rises will affect the world economy. These numbers are therefore too uncertain to act on. Sir Nicholas may well err on the gloomy side. And it is certainly impossible to predict precisely what effect climate change will have had on the world economy in a century's time. But neither point invalidates Sir Nicholas's central perception—that governments should act not on the basis of the likeliest outcome from climate change but on the risk of something really catastrophic (such as the melting of Greenland's ice sheet, which would raise sea levels by six to seven metres). Just as people spend a small slice of their incomes on buying insurance on the off-chance that their house might burn down, and nations use a slice of taxpayers' money to pay for standing armies just in case a rival power might try to invade them, so the world should invest a small proportion of its resources in trying to avert the risk of boiling the planet. The costs are not huge. The dangers are."

See Stern Report: Executive Summary; and a Review, and a Critique, and a rejoinder by Ken Arrow (one of the greatest), and the latest (Nov. 2007) IPCC report on climate change
 
See, also:  World Economics, 7 (2), April/June 2006:
Nicholas Stern: "What is the ecoonomics of climate change? (1 - 11)
Ian Byatt et al.: "The Stern Review 'OXONIA' Papers: a critique", (145 152)
Nicholas Stern: "Reply to Byatt et al.", (153 - 158).

See here for a little more on this vital issue.

Comments and Suggestions??



Back to Index.

Back to DRH Class Index