DEVELOPMENT PROCESSES - SOME IDIOSYNCRATIC THOUGHTS
1. SOME BRIEF BACKGROUND - A FLAVOUR
OF THE DEBATES
What is Development?
-
Increase in availablilty and improved distribution of essentials: (survival)
-
food
-
shelter
-
protection from natural or external threat
-
health
-
Raise standards of living for all (efficiency and effectiveness)
-
more jobs
-
more income
-
better education
-
Expand the range of personal and social choice and freedom to choose -
civilisation? - (being a peasant may be pleasant, but only if you
can chose whether or not to stay being one rather than do or be something
else)
What does it mean to be underdeveloped?
-
Under-resourced: Poor, illiterate and ill-educated, under-resourced,
limited choices - subsistence and food/shelter provision takes up most
effort, with little left over for enjoyment or investment.
-
Over-populated - too many people trying to scratch a living from too few
resources
-
Low productivity - not much out for the effort put in (lack of appropriate
technology, or lack of training/skill, or too much risk of starvation associated
with available technologies)
-
General inequality - a few manage to be relatively well provided for, at
the apparent expense of the many condemned to subsistence
What does Development mean (what is growth)?
-
Increase in GDP per head, which can only result from:
-
increased capital stock (equipment etc. (including land improvment)) -implies
either increased savings or inward investment.
-
improved technologies for converting inputs into outputs
-
improved management of resources (better allocation of resources to production
activites, and better mix of production activities to generate income)
-
Increase in Total GDP -
-
increase in population, associated with an increase in GDP per head
-
Increasing diversity and differentiation in socio-economic activity and
occupation, and associated increase in consumer choice - implying structural
transformation of the economy, especially the declining importance of agriculture
as an occupation
-
Increasing complexity and sophistication of social and ideological bases
for society
-
Increasing trade and geo-poliotical linkages with the rest of the world
-
Increasing divergance between the haves and have-nots?? (see below)
Theories:
"Development economics has no universally accepted doctrine or paradigm.
Instead we have a continually evolving pattern of insights and understandings
that together provide the basis for examining the possibilities of contemporary
development. ... Successful development requires a skillful and judicious
balancing of market priocing and promotion where markets can exist and
operate efficiently, along with intelligent and equity-oriented government
intervention in areas where unfettered market forces would lead to undesirable
economic and social outcomes." (Michael Todaro, Economic Development,
7th edition, Addison-Wesley, 2000, p 102-103)
One enduring characterisation of the debates about development is the
contrast between:
-
Dependence - underdevelopment a consequence of external exploitation or
colonisation etc. (underdevelopment caused by inappropriate and inequitable
distribution
of gains from development and trade between the rich and the poor)
-
Inherent/Internal - underdevelopment a consequence of tyranny, poor governance,
market failures, lack of appropriate market institutions and rules, fraud
& corruption etc. (underdevelopment essentially problems of economic
efficiency
(resource allocation) - market failures, many caused by government or policy
failures)
For a recent and rather public debate over quantity versus quality of
growth (the latter referring to the "development" dimensions of growth),
see the Economist critique of the World Bank's
present strategies and the World Bank's reply.
Inequality versus Poverty Alleviation? One of
the Major current debates - does economic growth necessarily require growing
inequality?
-
Does economic growth lead to reduced poverty?
-
recent history (1980 - 1998) suggests that total numbers in absolute poverty
is pretty stationary (1.2bn people with incomes less than $1/per day, as
estimated on a consistent basis by the World Bank - declining since 1980
by 200m people), so proportion is falling (from 31% to 20% of the world's
population over 18 years) since world population is still rising. This
is a pretty spectacular counter-argument to those who suggest that globalisation
condemns more people to poverty and only benefits the rich.
-
Average Incomes per head between countries is becoming more, not less,
equal (when weighted by population), though rapid growth in both India
and China are largely repsonsible for this - excluding these two very l;arge
countries alters the conclusion - with no obvioous trend since 1980.
However, what is the ground for excluing 40% of the world's population?
(60% in 1980
-
Income inequality may have tended to increase within countries in the recent
past, though the basis of these estimates are disputed. The world
Bank's experts (David Dollar and Aart Kraay (Foreign Affairs)) estimates
that world-wide income inequality peaked in the 1970s, and that the gap
between a randomly selected individual and the world average income per
head is now (1995) 78%, roughly were it was in 1950, while the peak in
1970 was 88%.
-
However, the evidence can be contested and scholars can be found who can
argue persuasively that inequality is growing rather than declining
-
Notwithstanding, it seems incontestable that fewer peope (even if still
an unacceptably large number) now die or are threatened with absolute starvation
than was the case in the 1950s - when awefully huge numbers did actually
die of starvation.
-
In any event, maybe the extent of world poverty is unacceptable to civilised
hearts and minds - 85% of world income goes to 20% of the population, and
6% to 60%. The absolute gap between rich and poor is still rising,
despite the proposition that relative poverty levels are falling (the poor
countries tending to grow faster, from low bases, than the rich - so the
relative gap is falling, although the absolute gap is still rising)
-
But what is the proposed solution to this? Even with a perfectly
equal distribution of income, normal individual life-cycle savings and
borrowings would result in 40% of the population owning 60% of the wealth.
-
Should the rich donate sufficient of the their earnings to the poor to
ensure absolute equality? What would be the consequences for incentives
and penalties to try and do better? In any event, if the rich will
not voluntarily increase their aid donations, what is the solution?
-
However, a significantly more equal world does seem likely to be more stable,
peaceful and thus prosperous.
-
Although one can quarrel with the numbers, and claim that we do not really
know how many poor there are, it does seem clear that more rapid economic
growth for the poorer regions is the only practical way of reducing poverty
- given that the rich are not going to increase their aid donations substantially
(unless successfully balckmailed by "terrorism", perhaps)
-
Does liberalisation, deregulated markets, prudent macroeconomics (fiscal
balance and low inflation) necessarily produce growth? Or are these
exhibitions those of the successful countries, whose growth is otherwise
explained by diffusion of technical capacity and adaptation? It seems
clear that agricultural protection has been employed by most developed
countries in the interests of income equalisation (protection of declining
industries), and only when countries become substantially rich are they
willing to reduce this protection.
-
Biggest Policy challenge is to accelerate economic growth in poor countries
-
Open markets and foreign direct investment both make important contributions
to such growth
-
Self-sufficiency and protection does not help such growth.
-
But do these propositions necessarily mean that full and complete liberalisation
of markets is necessarily always a good thing (what about encouraging domestic
and local industries?) or necessarily the top priority (there are other
things which are necessary to achieve growth)
Reference: World Bank Progress in Poverty
Reduction (Executive Summary), following the World Development Report,
2000/2001.
What is the Development Process?
Streeten (What Price Food?: Agricultural Price Policies in Developing
Countries, Macmillan, 1987) encapsulates the necessary elements of an effective
economic system for the production and distribution of food under the 6
I headings:
-
Innovation technology, especially irrigation, varieties of crops
and livestock, and appropriate management practices;
-
Incentives the right prices for outputs and inputs);
-
Inputs need to be available and accessible, including credit);
-
Infrastructure transportation and storage, as well as properly functioning
markets, including the management of risk);
-
Institutions - the rules and procedures and accepted practices rather
than the specific organisations, especially for: laws of contract, lack
of fraud, marketing and land ownership & operation and property rights
- (the social infrastructure, if you like);
-
Information - the extension of techniques as well as marketing information
and credit availabilities.
With these elements in place, it is possible to expect the market system
to deliver appropriate and affordable supplies in the right places at the
right times and in the right forms.
Peter Hazell, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington,
presents a brief but highly relevant and articulate summary of the problems
facing the world in
securing food supplies without compromising the environmental base
on which it depends in the Introduction to a Special Issue of the journal:
Agricultural Economics
(Elsevier) on Agricultural Growth, Poverty, and the Environment, Vol
19, Nos 1-2, September, 1998. In summary:
-
Hunger and malnutrition persist, often because past agric. growth was insufficient
or failed to benefit the poor (exacerbated by national mismanagement and,
in extremis, civil conflict).
-
Increases in popn. growth and per capita incomes -> increasing demand ->
continued increases in agric. productivity, against evidence of some slowing
in this.
-
Growth in productivity and limited prospects for expansion of cropped and
irrigated areas.
-
Environmental problems could check this increase in productivity further,
as well as imposing health, welfare and environmental costs both nationally
and
-
Internationally: where environmental issues generally fall into two categories:
over-intensification (typical of developed countries); over-population
relative to existing agricultural technology and practice, leading to depletion
of natural resource and expansion into more fragile areas (frequently in
LDCs)
"Continued agriucltural growth will be a necessity, not an option,
for most developing countries. .... These three goals (growth, poverty
alleviation and environmental
sustainability) are not necessarily complementary, and cannot be taken
for granted. But a high degree of complementarity is more likely to be
achieved when agricultural
development is: a) broadly based and involves small and medium sized
farms; b) market driven; c) participatory and decentralised; d) driven
by productivity enhancing
technological change that does not degrade the resource base."
The post-war history of international development assistance can
be roughly described as falling into the following phases:
1950s - 1960s: generating the requirements for agricultural growth as
the 6 Is above.
1970s - 1980s: focus shifted to reduce poverty and food insecurity,
and added six 'equity modifiers' to the 6 Is for growth, as follows;
-
Broad-based development - small and medium farms critical, since economies
of scale at farm level are limited (especially in labour rich and capital
poor economies), means prioritising smaller farms for inputs, credit, technology,
marketing
-
Land reforms - where productive land is too concentrated amongs plantations
or larger farms
-
Invest in Human capital - education, clean water, health, family planning
and nutrition
-
Women important in the development process and warrant targeted programmes
-
Particiaption of all in development is critical
-
Rural non-farm economy needs promotion and development
1990s: focus on environmental sustainability - where the key principles
are still being worked out. Hazell suggests the following:
-
Priority to backward regions and resource poor areas (where the threat
of over-use is greatest)
-
R&D should concentrate on broader aspects of land management at watershed
and landscape levels, as well as environmental impacts and effects at farm
and field levels
-
Secure property rights over land and natural resources, making full use
of indigenous practices and systems (incluidng either privatising common
property resources, or strengthening community rights and management systems
-
Resolve externalities through taxes on polluters or degraders (where free
market prices may well not be optimal for resource sustainablity
-
Devlolve and improve public or common management and institutional systems
-
Correct price distortions (remove subsidies on inputs, though make sure
the input supply is effective and competitive)
-
Monitor resource use and degradation, and educate population on the effects
Essential preconditions for growth?
-
A stable State (government), coupled with prudent macroeconomic management
- fiscal responsibility and monetary stability & security.
-
Security of the person and of property
-
Widespread literacy and numeracy
-
Basic health
-
Adequate infrastructure
-
Lack of bureaucratic red-tape and corruption
-
Broad acceptance of market forces
-
Financial system capable of transfering savings to effective uses
-
Possibly some inequality in income and asset distribution (with the rich
investing more, in more concentrated and managed form, than the poor)?
Role of Agriculture in Development?
-
Traditional view that industrialisation led and farming followed (as in
Western Europe??)
-
Non agricultural sectors expanding, sucking labour out of subsistence farming
and rural areas and into factories
-
Industrialisation providing the technology for commercial farming to feed
the workforce with far fewer people
-
A more historically balanced view is that
-
agricultural technical and productivity change, (Jethro Tull's seed drill
in the UK) allows fewer people to feed more non farm people
-
but only if coupled with +/- serious land reform, in which previously subsistance
farmers leave the land to commercial agriculture
-
and with market development (at least first in the rural areas where most
people live) in other sectors than agriculture, increasing the demand for
purchased food from the commerical farms and providing the pull factors
to encourage people to give up subsistance farming (requires secure and
relatively stable markets)
-
leads to the the development of an 'industrial' domestic agriculture (few
people and large marketable surplus), also led to an industrialisation
and commercialisation of the countryside.
-
the industrial revolution (substituting steam for animal and human power,
and mineral reosurces and engineering for timber) leads to further commercialisation
and concentration of industry in larger scale and mainly urban factories
-
{where the development process in the New World was also different in the
exploitation of 'virgin' lands - denied the present generation of LDCs
and economies in transition}
-
What does seem clear is that, in most cases, development involves fewer
people earning a full time living from farming, and more people earning
livings from other things. Agriculture is a declining industry in
the development process, but can only be so if it becomes more productive.
The only exception is in those regions and countries which develop a substantial
food export capacity - allowing agriculture to be a leading rather than
declining sector.
-
What is also apparent from a general view of history is that people (especially
when supported by democracy) are not willing to leave the declining sector
to the mercy of the market, but seek to support their ancestral heritage
(small and subsistence farmers) as and when they become rich and secure
enoug to do so - farm support policies are ubiquitous amongst developed
countries.
-
It is also clear that market price support and protection (based on production)
are by far the most obvious and popular forms of such support. If
the world (through the URAA and the WTO) have now decided that these forms
of support are not to be allowed, then there is a serious challenge
to policy makers and advisors to provide some equivalently obvious and
apparent system of support and transfer to the declining sectors in developing
and transition economies. It is not clear that policy analysis and
development is yet up this challenge.
Major Relevant Reference and Source Sites:
UK DfID (Department for
International Development) - with its own list of relevant links - see
their Development Forum. "Sustainable Livelihoods" is the current
major focus of DfID, echoing and amplifying much of the current thinking
in the World Bank.
World Bank - especially their
annual World Development Reports
International Food Policy Research
Institute (IFPRI) see, especially, IFPRI's
2020 Vision programme. (the 2020
briefs are an especially useful source of condensed reports on findings
of IFPRI's research and policy development.) You may also find their
overview of the world's food supply and demand balance (2020
Global Food Outlook) interesting and useful.
UNCTAD (United Nations
Conference on Trade and Development) (see also UNCTAD's recent Trade and
Development Reports (e.g. their 2000 report,
overview here)
The December, 2001 (19,4) issue of Development Policy Review
(Blackwells), available via the Ingenta listing of e-journals through the
University Library, contains a whole issue of highly relevant and useful
review articles on several different aspects of rural and agricultural
development - well worth a substantial visit. Unfortunately, the
Robinson Library does not subscribe to this journal, so you can only see
the abstracts without paying! I am exploring the possibility of buying
the relevant articles to use as a student resource! Will let you
know how I get on.
2. A PERSONAL VIEW
A The Essential Logic
Human systems are living systems - they follow a Darwinian
logic - making the best possible use of available resources according
to the socio-economic and political pressures ruling at the time (which
determine the best fit of allocation of scarce resources to best
uses), and making use of such technolgies and techniques as are available,
tried, tested and trusted. The best-fitted systems and organisms
(firms, organisations etc.) grow better and replicate faster than those
which do not fit.
In such systems, specialisation of function and trade
between entities
(people, communities, localities, regions, sectors
and states) are necessary characteristics.
In this sense, Economics is very largely simply a respecification
of the principles of darwinian evolution and the survival of the fittest
- not, notice, the winner taking all, nor, by and large, domination by
single species (except in the most malign, sparse and poor environments).
Economic development, then, should lead to richer environments and greater
diversity. How does this happen in evolutionary systems?
The development process happens as a result of experiments
and innovations - new ways of doing things, both technical and institutional
(the human rules and habits governing how we do things and for what purpose).
Natural development is the result of historical accidents - most of which
fail, and only a few succeed - and are then able to replicate, breed, multiply
and succeed. Arguably, most human (socio-economic) development has
also happened by accident - most favourable innovations surviving and replicating
while less favourable developments tend not to be able to compete - in
the ecological sense.
As with natural ecologies, development status is necessarily context
and circumstance specific (where you are and where you come from matter).
The richer the habitats (the more resources) the more extensive and diverse
will be the ecologies (economies), but these will differ from one another
if they are isolated - the Galapagos and Australasia for example, though
available niches will tend to be filled with similar organisms in the sense
of filling the same place and role in the food chains and cycles.
Isolated ecologies, though, tend to be vulnerable to invasion and invasive
species, which are better fitted to the environment than the natives.
Furthermore, naturally developing ecologies tend to develop their own
resource base - making soil from rock etc. - via re-cycling their
food stuffs - the socio-economic counterparts being the circular flow of
income and the flows of information and knowledge, habits and rules.
In this sense, living systems accumulate resources and capacities.
But human systems are different from natural systems - human
systems
self-select, whereas natural systems are naturally
selected. Humans think they can make the rules about who lives and
who dies, who prospers and who does not. It is the self-selection systems
which are critical in human development processes - what signals, incentives
and penalities are attached to certain forms of behaviour and activity?
The market system provides one set of incentives and penalties
- through explicit or implicit prices on goods, services and factors
of production, and thus on the returns and incomes to be made from various
activities and the choices made about what to consume and how much to save.
This system - the competitive market place - operates largely according
to natural principles - surivival, prosperity and replication of the fittest
- leading to obvious inequality, but limited accumulation of power over
the natural selection process - the large are necessarily most vulnerable
to disruption of their food chains, and are frequently indicator species
- a signal of the richness and diversity of the whole surrouinding ecology.
Market power (the ability of producers to dictate what and for whom) is
regarded as a market failure, which needs social governance (typically
formal government) to offset and overcome.
Our governance systems - from local habits and customs to formal
government rules and regulations - provide the other major set of incentives
and penalties - which does admit of power, and the fundamental exercise
of self-selection rather than natural selection. Power, then, is
the ability to choose and the associated ability to persuade or require
others to make particular choices.
The implication is that development is a reflection of the interaction
of all these constituent parts and mechanisms - no one part is inherently
more or less important than ay other - it is fit which counts, what will
fit with what in any particular context and circumstance? If we change
the context and circumstance, we will get a different (not necessarily
better or worse) development pattern. If we change one part (such
as substituting democratic control for autocratic control) this will have
different consequences depending on what other systems we have in place
and what resource base we have.
Trade and specialisation (market systems) naturally evolve in human
systems through and from barter as the most efficient and effective ways
of making the best use of available resources. All other forms of
human interaction associated with doing things will tend to involve higher
transactions costs (be less efficient or effective) except in special circumstances,
such as small and highly cohesive communities and families (the human organisation
equivalent of single species) - when different organisations or communities
(different species) compete for use of the same resources, then the market
system - natural selection - tends to take over as the most efficient form
of transaction/transformation. Ecologies do this through the transmission
and transformation of food and energy (the various biological and bio-physical
cycles), while economies do it through economic cycles, like the circular
flow of income and the interactions between markets.
However, markets and natural selection require that the final arbiter
of who lives and dies is external, as a given outside determinant (g.o.d.)
- in the natural selection case, as the laws of bio-physics governing the
nature of the transactions and transformations of food and energy, and
the possibilities for improvement or adjustment/adpatation of practice
within these laws. In the human case, governance takes over from
the bio-physical laws as the final arbiter. Markets exist and are
allowed to thrive only insofar as their societies will let them and encourage
them. Hence, it is these governance systems (our habits and rules
of social organisation - called institutions by North) which are the key
elements of the development process.
Prudent and sensible macroeconomic management (requiring stable and
legitimate (legitimised) government) is generally a necessary precursor,
as are the major elements of a functioing market system. However,
neither of these is sufficient to ensure sensible development, and both
could, perhaps, be overcome by socio-political governance of the 'right'
type - i.e. the type which best fits existing contexts and circumstances.
B Some Implications
-
Development Processes are necessarily unique to the time and space
within which they happen - the development experience of, e.g. western
europe or north america, will be different from each other and will almost
certainly not be replicated by other countries development trajectories
or opportunities. For example, the major development phase of the
industrial revolution (driven by an extraordinary harnessing of fossil
fuels and minerals to the engine of engineering innovation, and more lately
production line manufacturing and processing) is unlikely to be repeated
in quite the same way now - it has happened already and when and as it
happens again (as in India, for instance) it will happen differently.
Similarly, the extraordinary development of North America cannot happen
again (as the exploitation of a territory treated as virgin by groups of
refugees and ex-patriots from elsewhere).
-
The Processes are probably much more important than the structures
- who builds and runs a dam, for what purposes and according to whoe priorities,
and who gets the rewards, is much more important than the dam itself -
similarly with socio-economic organisations such as private companies,
banks etc.
-
But, mostly our present theories and understandings have to do with
structures rather than processes - so our abilities to analyse and understand
development is likely to be confused and confusing. Hence - development
remains a very significant challenge to social sciences and practitioners.
-
Just possibly, notions more akin to husbandry, cultivation, selective breeding,
nurture etc. are more useful to understanding development than much of
our more conventional social science tool kits (from whatever discipline).
Culture, not just agriculture, is a key?
-
But, if so, who governs the cultivators? The answer must be that
future history will govern present cultivators - those trying to do the
development. If it works and fits, it will perpetuate and the future
history will judge and govern the present developers. if it doesn't
work, then the present developers will not find their work and ideas replicated.
Problem - this is small comfort to those who are required (through no available
alternatives) to suffer the present development experiments.
-
The only alternative is to develop a common framework within which
the development processes can be commonly understood and discussed - which
we do not have at present. Without this, we cannot hope to avoid
the stupid mistakes by taslking about them and thinkning about them before
we commit to them.
Which is why I am trying (off and on, or even most of the time) to develop
an outline and logic of what such a common framework might look like -
which would allow us to trade and exchange ideas and concepts and perspectives,
and thus learn both from each other, and also from the very process of
trade in ideas. The present state of this ridiculously ambitious
research agenda is outlined here, for anyone
interested, with some further background on my research
web-site.
C. Some other evidence?
Jared Diamond: Guns, Germs and Steel, a short history of everybody
for the last 13,000 years., Vintage, London, 1998, addresses the question
of why some societies (especially the north west, seem to have made different
progress than other societies, which, furthermore, appear to have become
the dominant socieities in the present world. His underlying rationale
is: "History followed different course for different people because of
differences among people's environments, not because of biological differences
among people themselves" (p 25). The germ of his argument (thesis,
story), which is a good read, is as follows:
-
The proximate causes of European expansion into (especially) the Americas
appear to be:
-
European germs wipping out native peoples
-
Horses (unknown in South America)
-
Literacy (enabling habits, conventions and institutions to be replicated
between generations with more certainty)
-
Political organisation - collective action
-
Technology - especially guns
-
Ultimate Causes of these 'advantages'?
-
Food production and cultivation (the progression from hunter-gatherer
to farmer - depended on the availability of cultivable and domesticable
plants and animals - only locally available grasses (cereals) and domesticable
animals, all to be found in central europe but not, typically, elsewhere.
-
which could spread only in specific directions, governed by the early
geography of the planet
-
and which allowed for the development of dense populations, which generated
diseases particularly adapted to such populations
-
and which also generated the advantages of writing - to pass on
the lessons of cultivation and also enable the necessary transactions between
commercial farmers and the rest of the population (involving money and
contracts).
-
and which also allowed for specialisation, including the development
of a craftsman and ultimately inventor, entreprenurial and bureaucracy
(governing and organising) classes -> technology & political organisation
(and necessary investment)
-
aided and abetted by relative abundance of raw materials (coal and iron).
Back to AEF811 Index.