DEVELOPMENT PROCESSES - SOME IDIOSYNCRATIC THOUGHTS

1.    SOME BRIEF BACKGROUND - A FLAVOUR OF THE DEBATES

What is Development? What does it mean to be underdeveloped? What does Development mean (what is growth)? Theories:
"Development economics has no universally accepted doctrine or paradigm.  Instead we have a continually evolving pattern of insights and understandings that together provide the basis for examining the possibilities of contemporary development.  ... Successful development requires a skillful and judicious balancing of market priocing and promotion where markets can exist and operate efficiently, along with intelligent and equity-oriented government intervention in areas where unfettered market forces would lead to undesirable economic and social outcomes." (Michael Todaro, Economic Development, 7th edition, Addison-Wesley, 2000, p 102-103)
One enduring characterisation of the debates about development is the contrast between: For a recent and rather public debate over quantity versus quality of growth (the latter referring to the "development" dimensions of growth), see the Economist critique of the World Bank's present strategies and the World Bank's reply.

Inequality versus Poverty Alleviation?  One of the Major current debates - does economic growth necessarily require growing inequality?

Reference:  World Bank Progress in Poverty Reduction (Executive Summary), following the World Development Report, 2000/2001.
 

What is the Development Process?

Streeten (What Price Food?: Agricultural Price Policies in Developing Countries, Macmillan, 1987) encapsulates the necessary elements of an effective economic system for the production and distribution of food under the 6 I headings:

With these elements in place, it is possible to expect the market system to deliver appropriate and affordable supplies in the right places at the right times and in the right forms.

Peter Hazell, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, presents a brief but highly relevant and articulate summary of the problems facing the world in
securing food supplies without compromising the environmental base on which it depends in the Introduction to a Special Issue of the journal: Agricultural Economics
(Elsevier) on Agricultural Growth, Poverty, and the Environment, Vol 19, Nos 1-2, September, 1998. In summary:


"Continued agriucltural growth will be a necessity, not an option, for most developing countries. .... These three goals (growth, poverty alleviation and environmental
sustainability) are not necessarily complementary, and cannot be taken for granted. But a high degree of complementarity is more likely to be achieved when agricultural
development is: a) broadly based and involves small and medium sized farms; b) market driven; c) participatory and decentralised; d) driven by productivity enhancing
technological change that does not degrade the resource base."

The post-war history of international development assistance can be roughly described as falling into the following phases:

1950s - 1960s: generating the requirements for agricultural growth as the 6 Is above.

1970s - 1980s: focus shifted to reduce poverty and food insecurity, and added six 'equity modifiers' to the 6 Is for growth, as follows;

1990s: focus on environmental sustainability - where the key principles are still being worked out. Hazell suggests the following: Essential preconditions for growth? Role of Agriculture in Development?
Major Relevant Reference and Source Sites:
UK DfID  (Department for International Development) - with its own list of relevant links - see their Development Forum.  "Sustainable Livelihoods" is the current major focus of DfID, echoing and amplifying much of the current thinking in the World Bank.
World Bank - especially their annual World Development Reports
International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI) see, especially, IFPRI's 2020 Vision programme. (the 2020 briefs are an especially useful source of condensed reports on findings of IFPRI's research and policy development.)  You may also find their overview of the world's food supply and demand balance (2020 Global Food Outlook) interesting and useful.
UNCTAD (United Nations Conference on Trade and Development) (see also UNCTAD's recent Trade and Development Reports (e.g. their 2000 report, overview here)
The December, 2001 (19,4) issue of Development Policy Review (Blackwells), available via the Ingenta listing of e-journals through the University Library, contains a whole issue of highly relevant and useful review articles on several different aspects of rural and agricultural development - well worth a substantial visit.  Unfortunately, the Robinson Library does not subscribe to this journal, so you can only see the abstracts without paying!  I am exploring the possibility of buying the relevant articles to use as a student resource!  Will let you know how I get on.


2.    A PERSONAL VIEW

A    The Essential Logic

Human systems are living systems - they follow a Darwinian logic - making the best possible use of available resources according to the socio-economic and political pressures ruling at the time (which determine the best fit of allocation of scarce resources to best uses), and making use of such technolgies and techniques as are available, tried, tested and trusted.  The best-fitted systems and organisms (firms, organisations etc.) grow better and replicate faster than those which do not fit.

In such systems, specialisation of function and trade between entities (people, communities, localities, regions, sectors and states) are necessary characteristics.

In this sense, Economics is very largely simply a respecification of the principles of darwinian evolution and the survival of the fittest - not, notice, the winner taking all, nor, by and large, domination by single species (except in the most malign, sparse and poor environments).  Economic development, then, should lead to richer environments and greater diversity.  How does this happen in evolutionary systems?

The development process happens as a result of experiments and innovations - new ways of doing things, both technical and institutional (the human rules and habits governing how we do things and for what purpose).  Natural development is the result of historical accidents - most of which fail, and only a few succeed - and are then able to replicate, breed, multiply and succeed.  Arguably, most human (socio-economic) development has also happened by accident - most favourable innovations surviving and replicating while less favourable developments tend not to be able to compete - in the ecological sense.

As with natural ecologies, development status is necessarily context and circumstance specific (where you are and where you come from matter).  The richer the habitats (the more resources) the more extensive and diverse will be the ecologies (economies), but these will differ from one another if they are isolated - the Galapagos and Australasia for example, though available niches will tend to be filled with similar organisms in the sense of filling the same place and role in the food chains and cycles.  Isolated ecologies, though, tend to be vulnerable to invasion and invasive species, which are better fitted to the environment than the natives.

Furthermore, naturally developing ecologies tend to develop their own resource base - making soil from rock etc. - via re-cycling their food stuffs - the socio-economic counterparts being the circular flow of income and the flows of information and knowledge, habits and rules.  In this sense, living systems accumulate resources and capacities.

But human systems are different from natural systems - human systems self-select, whereas natural systems are naturally selected.  Humans think they can make the rules about who lives and who dies, who prospers and who does not. It is the self-selection systems which are critical in human development processes - what signals, incentives and penalities are attached to certain forms of behaviour and activity?

The market system provides one set of incentives and penalties - through explicit or implicit prices on goods, services and factors of production, and thus on the returns and incomes to be made from various activities and the choices made about what to consume and how much to save.  This system - the competitive market place - operates largely according to natural principles - surivival, prosperity and replication of the fittest - leading to obvious inequality, but limited accumulation of power over the natural selection process - the large are necessarily most vulnerable to disruption of their food chains, and are frequently indicator species - a signal of the richness and diversity of the whole surrouinding ecology.  Market power (the ability of producers to dictate what and for whom) is regarded as a market failure, which needs social governance (typically formal government) to offset and overcome.

Our governance systems - from local habits and customs to formal government rules and regulations - provide the other major set of incentives and penalties - which does admit of power, and the fundamental exercise of self-selection rather than natural selection.  Power, then, is the ability to choose and the associated ability to persuade or require others to make particular choices.

The implication is that development is a reflection of the interaction of all these constituent parts and mechanisms - no one part is inherently more or less important than ay other - it is fit which counts, what will fit with what in any particular context and circumstance?  If we change the context and circumstance, we will get a different (not necessarily better or worse) development pattern.  If we change one part (such as substituting democratic control for autocratic control) this will have different consequences depending on what other systems we have in place and what resource base we have.

Trade and specialisation (market systems) naturally evolve in human systems through and from barter as the most efficient and effective ways of making the best use of available resources.  All other forms of human interaction associated with doing things will tend to involve higher transactions costs (be less efficient or effective) except in special circumstances, such as small and highly cohesive communities and families (the human organisation equivalent of single species)  - when different organisations or communities (different species) compete for use of the same resources, then the market system - natural selection - tends to take over as the most efficient form of transaction/transformation.  Ecologies do this through the transmission and transformation of food and energy (the various biological and bio-physical cycles), while economies do it through economic cycles, like the circular flow of income and the interactions between markets.

However, markets and natural selection require that the final arbiter of who lives and dies is external, as a given outside determinant (g.o.d.) - in the natural selection case, as the laws of bio-physics governing the nature of the transactions and transformations of food and energy, and the possibilities for improvement or adjustment/adpatation of practice within these laws.  In the human case, governance takes over from the bio-physical laws as the final arbiter.  Markets exist and are allowed to thrive only insofar as their societies will let them and encourage them.  Hence, it is these governance systems (our habits and rules of social organisation - called institutions by North) which are the key elements of the development process.

Prudent and sensible macroeconomic management (requiring stable and legitimate (legitimised) government) is generally a necessary precursor, as are the major elements of a functioing market system.  However, neither of these is sufficient to ensure sensible development, and both could, perhaps, be overcome by socio-political governance of the 'right' type - i.e. the type which best fits existing contexts and circumstances.

B   Some Implications

Which is why I am trying (off and on, or even most of the time) to develop an outline and logic of what such a common framework might look like - which would allow us to trade and exchange ideas and concepts and perspectives, and thus learn both from each other, and also from the very process of trade in ideas.  The present state of this ridiculously ambitious research agenda is outlined here, for anyone interested, with some further background on my research web-site.

C.    Some other evidence?
Jared Diamond: Guns, Germs and Steel, a short history of everybody for the last 13,000 years., Vintage, London, 1998, addresses the question of why some societies (especially the north west, seem to have made different progress than other societies, which, furthermore, appear to have become the dominant socieities in the present world.  His underlying rationale is: "History followed different course for different people because of differences among people's environments, not because of biological differences among people themselves" (p 25).  The germ of his argument (thesis, story), which is a good read, is as follows:


Back to AEF811 Index.