ACE8021: SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT & ENVIRONMENTAL CHANGE

SESSION ON ECONOMICS & SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT

Prof. David Harvey. (Last Update: 14.02.13)
Comments and Suggestions??

See Here for a critique of the arguments presented in one of the Course Texts: Dresner, S., The Principles of Sustainability, Earthscan, 2002.

Aim:    to identify,  examine and discuss the critical economic features of the concept of sustainability.

Objective:    to develop an appreciation and general understanding of:

[Difficulties:  these aims and objectives are not consistent with a session amounting to less than 15% of the total module time. The issues and problems, and necessary background information, will necessarily be dealt with in highly abbreviated and condensed form]


Index of topics covered in these notes & this session:


A.  The First Principles of Economic Systems

1.    The Laws of thermodynamics (which apply to ALL CLOSED SYSTEMS - with no external inputs) underpin economic (and all other) systems. The first two laws are:
  1. Materials Balance Princple: Neither matter nor energy can be created or destroyed: total mass-energy is fixed:  all apparent changes are conversions of one form into others. So, the more matter and energy an economy (people) uses, the more natural resource depletion and waste it will generate.
  2. The Entropy Principle: where entropy is a measure of disorder. In a closed system, the use of mass-energy results in a one way flow from low entropy resources (mass-energy) to high entropy resources, from order to disorder. Perpetual motion is impossible - use of energy leads to dissipation of energy into unusable forms (disorder), all we can do is release order, and generate disorder. All closed systems tend to run down and dissipate to disorder, towards maximum entropy. NO CLOSED SYSTEM IS ULTIMATELY SUSTAINABLE. (Though the earth is not closed - it continually receives enrgy from the sun - the solar system is (for practical purposes), closed, and the sun is runnning down.) So, any discussion of sustainability has to recognise that sustainability is a relative, not absolute concept. Are some processes and activities more or less sustainable than others?
Back to Index.

2.    Ecology: Man is an Animal: whose population will expand to exhaust its local food supplies or life support systems, and then contract (through disease, starvation etc, and, in the case of man alone, wars and conflicts) to a sustainable level, consistent with the local environment - the Malthusian Principle. The world population has grown from 0.5bn in 1600 to 1.6bn in 1900, to 6 bn. in 2000, and is on track to grow to 9 billion or perhaps more by 2100, with the population explosion coinciding with the advent of the industrial revolution. It has achieved this through making massively more use of the planets resources, and creating more waste as a consequence.  There must be a limit to the human carrying capacity of the planet - but where is this limit?
Back to Index.

3.    The Circular Flow of Income describes the economic system:  One persons' spending is anothers' income.  There is no such thing as a free lunch (someone, somewhere is paying for it).  Income (and wealth, which is simply stored income) can only ultimately be created by using labour, land, solar energy (either directly or in stored form) and natural resources. 

However, as economic development (increased incomes and economic activity) occurs, most economic activity is concerned with further processing and delivery of final goods and services, and typically an increasing amount of service and secondary activity.  Each of these processes within the system is a process of adding value to the basic mix of land, labour (including management) capital (stored productive capacity in the form of machines and tools, etc.).  It is this added-value which provides peoples' incomes, based on their ownership of the basic factors (land, labour and capital). The key differentiation between developed economies and developing economies is the amount of capital per head employed by the economic system, though the quantity and quality of land also matters.

For those more at home with ecological and biological concepts, I suggest it helps to think of economic processes in much the same way as ecological and biological cycles, with income cycles similar to carbon, oxygen and water cycles. As these cycles operate, so biological growth and replication happens.  Innovation serves the same function within economics as mutation serves within biological cycles, and the survival of the fittest criterion for survival and continued replication in economics is simply that - the continued ability to make or scratch a living.  See here for a little more detail on this conception of the economic system.
Back to Index.

4.    Principles of Trade and Specialisation (Adam Smith's invisible hand) - the 'mechanics' of the economic process. No one can easily be entirely self-sufficient - to do so requires that we (as a household, village, or region) do everything for ourselves.  Adam Smith's account of the Wealth of Nations (1776) still remains as the foundation account of the market mechanism. The process is driven by four fundamental ideas:

"It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker that we expect our dinner," says Smith, "but from their regard to their self-interest."  If the butcher does not provide what his customers want, they will go elsewhere and his business will decline and thus his income will fall. Competition between butchers (and all other suppliers) means that no-one is able to make excessive profits for long - others will enter the (butchering) market if the present butchers are making a lot of money, and the prices that each can then charge will tend to fall as the customers trade one off against the other. So butchers' revenues and incomes will fall as more try to join the prosperous business.

If there are too many butchers - the supply of meat from the butchers is too great in the face of demand by customers -  then the prices they can charge will fall so low that some (at least) do not make enough to live on, and some will give up and seek something else to do. Prices and incomes for those remaining will then rise.

In the end, the market system should settle down so that each makes as great an income as possible, which is at least as much as each could make doing something else - in their next best alternative form of occupation (their opportunity costs). In so doing, customers (consumers) will find that they are supplied with as much as they are willing to buy (given their income) at a price which they are willing to pay. If not, there will be profit opportunities available for someone to increase supplies of those things which consumers want in greater quantities than are presently available.  If consumers are willing to pay more than it costs to produce something, then someone will find it profitable to increase supplies.

Because people are different, some people are better at doing one thing than another. In addition, people have different resources to work with - their land and capital (plant and equipment) is different.  As a result, it will generally pay people to specialise in production of one thing - the thing they are good at relative to what else they themselves might do - and then trade this output with others (producing different things), so making everyone better off than they would be if they all tried to be self-sufficient. 

Notice, especially, that specialisation makes sense even for those who are absolutely worse at doing everything than their neighbour or potential trader.  Even these people (or groups or regions) will be better at doing some things than others.  They will be comparatively good at something - compared with the other things they themselves could do.  They should specialise in their own comparative advantage, regardless of their absolute advantage.

If this proposition is not immediately convincing, just consider how busy you would be, and how little leisure time you would have, if you tried to be totally self-sufficient. Would you consider yourself to be better-off without the possibility of trade and exchange?  If so, why are you not already practicing complete self-sufficiency? I know you are not, because if you were, you would not be reading this.

Once again, the parallels with biological and ecological evolutionary systems are strong.  Individual people are similar to genes (thought of according the selfish gene concept (Dawkins)), while the organisms of biology are similar to the organisations (firms, households, political parties etc.), with the same gene (person) expressing itself in different ways according to the organism and the environment in which it finds itself.  People survive and replicate according to their ability to find and express themselves in surviving and replicating organisms (organisations).

This brief outline of the story of economic competition according to Adam Smith introduces (albeit breifly) eight key economic concepts:

See here, for an extended account of the logic of this simple story (explanation) of the way economies work.

Back to Index.


B. Economic meaning of and possibilities for sustainability?

1.    Meaning?

  1. From a simple economist's perspective, sustainability might be taken as the ability to maintain wealth, income, consumption and lifestyles indefinitely.
  2. Since the generation of income and wealth requires the use (exploitation) of both renewable and non-renewable natural and physical resources, and also generates waste and pollution, while at least part of peoples utility and enjoyment derives from appreciation and use of the natural environment and physical character of the planet, sustainability requires that the damage and depletion of the earth's natural resources and environment must be made good somehow, otherwise the processes of income generation will eventually run down. A common way of expressing this requirement is that human activity should be organised as if the human race had a full repairing lease on the planet -> sustainability translates into maintaining the productive capacity of the planet and all its parts: maintaining social, natural, physical and human capital stocks. (see, e.g. Arrow et.al.) - also the UN IHDP's 2012 Inclusive Wealth Report (highlighted by the Economist), which raise the question about  substitutability between different sorts of capital (human, social, natural and physical (produced))
  3. However, once stated in this way, most people (economists included) might well wish to add that the present distribution of wealth, income, consumption and living standards (quality of life) leaves a lot to be desired, and hence is socially (even morally) unsustainable.  So sustainability should also include the provision to improve welfare, especially of those currently less well-off.
  4. Once again, however, adding this proviso raises several more practical issues -
  5. Sustainability is typically taken to embrace or comprise three major axes: Social; Environmental; Economic.  This conception seems to imply that the major choices, decisions and judgements to be made about sustainability have to be made outside this three dimensional system (with some external/superior reference point?) - by the political institutions of the planet?  And, is technology irrelevant, even though it is arguably what got us into this state?
Back to Index.


2.    Possibilities?

i.    Market Failure Problems:  - externalities and public goods -> valuation and transaction cost problems

Markets depend on The critical factors giving rise to these problems are: None of these values can be infinite or invaluable - obtaining or preserving them always requires time, effort, inputs and resources, all of which could be used for other things - we have to make choices about what we do and what we produce or preserve, we cannot do everything.  Choice automatically implies an opportunity cost - what we might have done instead.  It will only be worthwhile to provide these things if the opportunity cost of providing them are lower than their values. Hence, their approximate value(always an underestimate) will the opportunity cost of their continued provision - if we do not think they are worth the effort, we will eventually stop providing for their preservation.

However, unless we actually require people to put their money (or their own time and effort) where their mouth is, we will frequently get very silly (inconsistent and incoherent) answers to apparently simple questions about how much a landscape, or a particular ecology is worth. If we think someone else will pay, it makes sense for us to pretend or imagine that the thing is very valuable indeed.  Once we are required to pay up to the value we think we place on the thing, we become very much more realistic about its worth in relative terms to the other things commanding our attention, resources and income. Economics (the market) cannot resolve these problems, except in very special circumstances. Solution requires collective action - governance - the long arm of the law is necessarily attached to the invisible hand of the market, not just to correct for market failure, but also to police the market system (outlaw theft, establish and policy property rights and the laws of contract, and make judgements about relative equity of market outcomes (changing these as seem fit).
Back to Index.

ii.    Problems of Substitution between physical (man-made) and natural capital -> valuation problems again

Sustainability implies at least a constant stock of Capital (both natural (Kn) and physical (man-made, Kk)). In the limit, maintaining a constant stock of natural capital denies the possibility of using any non-renewable resources (coal, oil, natural gas), and also denies the possibility of creating any waste. This strict form of capital sustainability is clearly unworkable (socially unsustainable). Some substitution of man-made capital (wind farms, solar energy panels, water power etc.) for natural capital is necessary for human systems to be termed sustainable. It must be possible to compensate for the loss of natural resources by building up stocks of physical (man-made) capital, otherwise human existence is inherently unsustainable above a very low level (perhaps 0.5 bn. people at subsistence levels of existence).  Are  you prepared to live like this?  If so, how are you going to decide what to do with all those who aren't?

As stocks of Kn are used up, so they will become scarcer, and thus more valuable (more expensive) - which will both encourage more efficient and economical use of the remaining stock, and encourage the search for and use of alternatives (renewables). We are already seeing some of these natural reactions, as renewable energy sources and energy efficiency measures become more attractive (energy use per £ of GDP is now considerably lower than it was), while we are becoming more concerned about waste disposal as the costs of damage become more obvious and the value of the natural environment increases (less of it per £ of GDP). However, there are 2 major problems with this natural (market) reaction to depletion of natural capital, each of which can compromise the resilience of market systems to cope with unforseen catastrophes.

  1. uncertainty and technological lags:  Increasing man made capital (Kk) is investing in the future - providing increased capacity to produce and consume at future dates. The future is uncertain.  The more uncertain it is, the lower the incentive to invest, since the probabilities of sufficient returns being generated to repay the investments are lower.  Furthermore, the greater the technical problems of developing alternatives, the longer the lag between recognising the need to invest and the provision of the alternative, and thus the greater the uncertainty and the lower the incentive. Long lead times, and large technological gaps mitigate against simply rational investment decisions - where simply rational means relying on probabilities of outcomes, and treating beneficial outcomes with the same weights as detrimental outcomes. We end up doing too little too late, because we are myopic, except that we don't always.
  2. irreversibility: the simple economic mechanisms tend to assume that economic processes are reversible - if we make mistakes, we can rectify them later. Burning up fossil fuel reserves which took 300 million years to accumulate in 300 years or so is nearly certain to have significant effects on global carbon balances and hence on global climate. But what will be the effects?  We remain uncertain, and we certainly don't know that they will be all bad, though there will be some bad effects.  It is tempting to suppose that we can make good, or at least make do and mend, if we fail to make the appropriate decisions now to limit (or even reduce) carbon emissions - that we can live with our mistakes. But this may turn out to be impossible, or impossibly expensive.  So surely it is more sensible to be cautious now - to adopt the precautionary principle (PP): if we don't know what the effects of certain actions will be, better to avoid them altogether, especially if the possible effects include serious and irreversible damage.  But universal adoption of this principle would eliminate many innovations and many experiments (trials by error), and limit our ability to cope with the future.  In the end, regardless of whether we are economists or not, we take decisions based on guesses about the relative merits - a balance between some guess about the possible benefits versus the possible costs. The PP really only amounts to the identification of those cases where the possible costs sufficiently exceed the possible benefits as to make the case (decision) daft. Deciding on these cases necesarily involves judgements about relative values of costs and benefits.
Underlying these difficulties are three more fundamental problems: the problem of valuation; the problem of capital; the problem of equity.

iii.    Identification and Valuation of non-market goods and services

This picture represents the typical problem of commerical farming (especially if subsidised) - that it uses land too intensively to be sustainable.
Intensity of Production (essentially the yields of biomass production per hectare, increased by the application of increased inputs) is measured along the horizontal axis.  The value of the effects of land use is measured on the vertical axis.
The Private (supported) Value of Biomass curve represents the net value (revenues minus all costs except land costs) of the subsidised production of biomass (food and fibre) on this particular hectare of land. It reaches a maximum value at intensity level B.
However, if we were to remove all the subsidies from this production, the net value curve would shift, so as to produce a maximum at intensity level P, the subsidies result in increased intensity of land use (and higher values to land under biomass production).
The remaining curves represent the values of other attributes and characteristics of the land use as intensity changes. (we might add a curve representing sporting rights and benefits as well, which would conflict with some other elements (wildlife) and complement others (other bits of wildlife).
The total social value of land curve is the vertical sum of each of the component curves (removing the subsidy from biomass production).  This total value reaches a maximum at point S.

Is this point (S) the sustainable point of intensity?
Identification of this point requires that the following critical components be identified:

  1. The biophysical consequences of particular land use decisions and practices for the rural environment ? the shapes and locations of the various curves (relationships) in physical terms as intensity is increased (and as production practices are changed).
  2. The behaviour of land managers and users in response to market or policy signals - showing what they will do under different market and policy conditions, and the decisions they will make about land use.
  3. The social valuations of the care (conservation, amenity, recreation and environmental) goods and services themselves - these are typically non-market goods and services, and it is difficult, but not impossible, to estimate peoples willingness to pay for these attributes and services. See here for some brief notes on the approaches.
Providing that we: Then can we expect market forces and a properly liberalised market to encourage land users to operate at the socially optimal level of intensity and multifunctionality at point S. Then we can regard this land use as sustainable - in the sense that we are properly accounting for the depletion of natural resources used in the production of food and fibre and properly accounting for the other competing and complimentary attributes of this land use.

Notice, however, that this characterisation of the problem is:

  1. Spatially heterogenous - there will be different curves (relationships) for different parcels of land
  2. Temporarly dynamic - these relationships will change through time as new techologies appear and as preferences and social valuations change
  3. Behaviourally heterogeneous - different people, as land onwers and land users, will respond differently to the same market and policy signals.
It is a complex system - which is not formally capable of prediction, but does generate replicating patterns and structures within certain boundary conditions.

iv.    Capital: Choices between now and the future (the tyranny of the discount rate)

As if the previous section were not complicated enough, dealing with the heterogenity across space and current behaviours, there is also an all important time dimension. Consider a policy to try and improve the sustainability of a particular land use (choose whatever example you like).  Suppose that we have all the necessary information (referred to above) to identify the costs and benefits of various forms of land use and their effects, and their social values.  This information will be contingent on current preferences, and on current technolgies, and on current capacities (land qualities, buildings, plant and equipment etc. in short on current capital stocks, both man made and natural).

But, we will discover that the biophysical attributes of the environment will be changed according to which land use we choose - the natural capital stock will change through time. So, too will the values people attach to these attributes (both individually and collectively). And, we may imagine, we could do better if we had and used different technologies.  In short, if we did things differently NOW, we would live in a different world in the FUTURE.  But, in order to decide whether or not we should do things differently now, we need to be able to compare the value of the different future conditions we generate with the costs of doing things differently now. Furthermore, the future is a stream of (annual) net benefits or costs, while NOW is a single value.

In simple terms, the value of the future might seem to be simply the sum of all the annual net benefits (NB(t), for each year t in the future) from a particular course of action, which can be compared with the current costs (K) of achieving this net benefit stream, where K is the investment necessary to achieve the future benefit stream.  But, for how long in the future - for ever?  Then any positive net benefit stream, however small the future benefits, will always outweigh the current costs, however large these may be, simply because the sum of an infinite stream is infinite. So this is clearly quite impractical as a guide to decision making.

It is also socially unsustainable - we do not behave as if the future were of exactly equivalent value as the present.

So long as the Capital Markets are working reasonably competitively (which they mostly do), these markets will balance personal time preference rates with the opportunity costs of capital to generate a interest rate - i.

Now we can compare current costs (K) with a future stream of net benefits (NBt).  NB1 - the net benefit we expect to get by the end of year 1, will need to be greater than our cost of securing this benefit now by at least the rate of interest, to make the current investment worthwhile.  So, if we invest £100 now, we need to be sure that our NB1 is at least £105 at a 5% interest rate (= £100 *(1.05)).  In other words, the Present Value (PV) (£100) is equivalent to a Future Value (FV) of £105)

So: FV1 = PV(1+i); or PV = FV1/(1+i).  This is the principle of discounting, where the interest rate is used as a discount rate - discounting the future value to its equivalent present value.  Repeating the same logic for year 2 gives FV2 = [PV(1+i)](1+i)] = PV(1+i2), so for year 2, PV = FV2/(1+i2), and so on as t increases.

The further into the future, the lower is the present value of the future benefit. This discounting of the future is even more severe if there is any uncertainty about our future return, since this uncertainty adds a risk premium to the discount rate.  The greater the uncertainty, the higher the risk premium.  Our behaviour is necessarily myopic - we could not make decisions over time unless this were the case.

Most modern mixed economies operate at a base interest rate (excluding inflation) of about 3 to 6%.  Simple arithmetic - the tyranny of discounting - quickly reduces anticipated future benefits to rather low present value at these rates of interest. For instance, £1000 in 30 years time is only worth £167 today, at a 5% discount or interest rate, and is only worth £333 today at a 2% discount rate.  Predecitions of general catastrophy in 50 years time, coupled with a considerable amount of uncertainty surrounding the nature of this catastrophe, does not warrent very large investments NOW.  Try getting people to pay for avoiding them, and see both the logic and the evidence of this.

The converse also applies:  to get £1000 in 30 years time, so long as there is no risk or uncertainty, we only have to invest £167 now, at 5%.  At 2% return, we will need to invest £333 now.  A little spent now might generate considerable returns in the future.

v.    Problems of Efficiency versus Equity (choices between us and them) (markets versus democracy)

There is a further complication to the assessment of costs and benefits - the distribution. Who pays the costs and who gets the benefits also matters. The market accords weight to those with the income and wealth - the more £s you have, the greater your votes in the market place for what you want in competition with everyone else.  Thus, those who own the resources get most of the say in what is produced and how, and for whom, and how much.

However, as humane societies, we also worry about caring for the less well off, at least some of the time, and expect our governments (and NGOs) to look after the poor on our behalf.  We might, therefore, be prepared to weight the interests of the poor (the benefits they may get) rather more highly than the interests of the rich?  Similarly, we may want to count the costs more highly if they are suffered by the poor rather than by the rich.  To do so requires that we use our governments, through democracy, to exercise these social and caring judgements on our behalf.

Does this mean that we should count future generations welfare at a higher level than our own?  Won't they be richer than us, providing our recent history of economic growth can be sustained?  Won't they be cleverer than us?

Does this mean that we should care more about the very poor, who live a long way away from us, than we care about the relatively poor on our own doorstep?

Questions of sustainability also raise these uncomfortable questions, which cannot be resolved through the market place, but need to be resolved through our governments, through collective action of some sort.


D. Conclusions and lessons learned?

THE PRINCIPLE CONCLUSIONS TO BE DRAWN FROM THESE CONSIDERATIONS CAN BE GROUPED UNDER TWO MAJOR HEADINGS: ECONOMICS AND SYSTEMS THEORY.
 
ECONOMICS: THERE IS NO SUCH THING AS A FREE LUNCH
SYSTEMS THEORY: SUSTAINABILITY IS RELATIVE: 
Treating the natural environment as if it were a free lunch is reckless, and potentially suicidal. The environment, and all its components, have a price. No system is absolutely sustainable except in a state of maximum entropy (complete chaos).
The human condition involves making choices. System persistence depends on buffering feedbacks which constrain explosive or implosive tendencies.
Making choices automatically implies a relative valuation of or judgement about outcomes versus inputs. But too much buffering prevents adaptation and response to changing conditions, and lowers resiliance to external (or unforseen) shocks.
There is no such thing as an invaluable asset - there is always a price at which people (as communities) will be willing to seek an alternative. Systems persist if they balance opposing forces and tendencies,  oscillating as a means of preserving these balances.
Valuations are critical, and are an expression of social choices To do so, they require a continual source of energy of some sort. Perpetual motion is impossible in a closed system.
The ways in which social choices are made are thus critical Human systems are no different, in principle, from biophysical systems.
The market is only one, albeit fundamental, way in which society makes choices Living systems (at least) evolve: they mind and respond, and so adapt to seek best fits with their biophysical environments.
The ways in which society learns to live with the natural processes of market transactions are critical to human sustainability. Human systems care and reply, as well as minding and responding, and thus learn (exhibiting Lamarkian adaptations: nurture breeds as well as grows new natures, which in turn replicate and evolve)
Social science is at least as important as natural science in making our systems more sustainable. In fact, if sustainability means sustaining human existence, social science has to be fundamental. Technology and Natural Science is not enough - these are simply tools.  The rules and reasons of use are more fundamentally important. Social Science needs to grow up, and breed a coherence and consistency which is currently lacking - this is (I think) the biggest challenge facing the Human race. See here for a possible beginning to this quest (as submitted to Ecological Economics)

See, also:
Dan Bromley:  "The poverty of sustainability: rescuing economics from platitudes."  Paper to International Association of Agricultural Economists, Durban, SA, August, 2003
DRH:  "Agri-environmental Relationships & Multifunctionality: Further Considerations", World Economy, 26 (5), May, 2003, 705 - 725
See here for notes on Climate Change.

Comments and Suggestions??



Back to Index.

Back to DRH Class Index