In simple terms, this principle says that it is better to concentrate your own scarce resources on making or doing the things that you are relatively good at, and to trade these things for those that you actually want. By so doing, you will be able to be better off (in terms of the quality and quantity of the things you consume and use) than if you tried to do and make everything for yourself. Remember the gains from trade arguments - the concept of a production possibility frontier and the choice sets opened up by trade? If not - go and revise this.
There are two important implications of this principle.
First, people get better at doing things and accumulate better and more resources (their production possibility frontiers (ppfs) move outwards). As they do, so the value of the things they produce will tend to decline, simply because more of them are being produced, and because they are costing less per unit to produce
Second, peoples tastes and preferences change, especially as their income, leisure time and general education changes. They will therefore alter what they are willing to pay for particular products and services, and this, too, can change the value of your comparative advantages, and may even shift your advantage from, say, beef production to the supply of farm holidays and conservation of remote landscapes and habitats. In other words, the terms of trade change depending on changes in ppfs and changes in preferences (and also get altered by changes in exchange rates in the case of internationallly traded goods and services).
Gains from trade are a result of exploiting the gains in productive efficiency arising from countries (or regions) concentrating on what they do best (produce most efficiently, or at least cost) and trading the products for those goods (and servies) for which this region/country is less efficient (making domestic production more expensive). The analytical logic of this argument can be found in any of the Economics Principles textbooks
Summary & Critique of Comparative Advantage logic
In general, specialisation and trade is advantageous because:
So, markets happen to allow people, sectors and regions to specialise and trade with each other, which in turn encourages the most efficient use of the available people and resources - producing more of what is wanted with a minimum use of resources (i.e. ensuring efficiency). In free markets, this specialisation and trade will tend to differentiate earnings of different factors (including people) according to their relative scarcity - the availability of the particular skill or resource compared with the demand for the use of the skill or resource (which in turn is derived from the demands for the products and services the resource produces).
Within a country, people and capital can and will move. There will be a flow of people and capital away from those regions and sectors which have relatively abundant resources and hence low returns towards those regions and sectors which have scarce resources and high (or more secure) returns. In the limit, this flow will equalise returns to resources (given their quality relative to demands for their particular capabilities) throughout the country. Differentials in rates of return will then reflect different qualities and be driven by the relative demands for these distinctive capabilities. The scarcer the particular resource capability relative to the demands for its use, the higher its return and the greater the incentives to create and develop other resources (people, land, capital) to imitate or duplicate these particular capabilities.
In the limit, within a country (defined here as a region within which there is free movement of capital and labour), trade and markets will result in an equalisation of prices for goods and services, and also an equalisation of returns to capital, labour and land (quality differences aside) across all sectors and regions. Differentials will simply reflect the costs of moving goods and services from one place, time or form to another, and similarly the costs of moving and changing labour, land and capital from one form or place to another. The greater the costs of transformation, the greater will be the persistent differentials. For example, if farmers are really determined to continue to be farmers whatever their returns, then they must expect the differential between their earnings as farmers and those in the rest of the economy to grow wider and wider (since the total earnings of farming relative to the total economy will inevitably decline as economies grow and spend more on other things than food)
Between countries, however, it is typically assumed that capital and labour mobility is more restricted - it is more costly to re-locate capital, and especially labour, between countries than within. People do not generally want to move, and will only move if the attractive incentives to move (or repulsive penalties for staying put) are sufficiently great. So, international labour, land and capital return differentials might be expected to be larger than within country differentials.
Free trade, however, will still tend to equalise prices between countries (with remaining differentials simply reflecting marketing costs) - the purchasing power parity theory of long-run exchange rates (see economic principles notes).
Rich countries, in this logic, are those with greater amounts of capital (especially) and land per head of the population and greater levels of skills, experience and education per head. These resources earn more per head than in poorer countries. Economic migration happens because people want to earn more, so they tend to gravitate towards those regions of the world with higher earnings.
There are two major counteracting forces preventing economic migration from equalising international wages and factor returns: a) people (especially) are typically reluctant to move away from their birthplaces, families and roots. The stronger and longer are the roots, the more reluctant they are to move, being content to remain relatively impoverished. The more impoverished they are, the less easy it is to move because the costs and risks are too great; b) the richer communities attempt to preserve and conserve their own wealth by preventing incomers and immigrants. Unless countries find themselves desparately short of particular forms of labour (typically unskilled, low waged or for menial or unpleasent jobs) entry to the richer regions will be restricted. Hence, wage equalisation is slow, costly and painful.
Capital, however, is increasingly internationally mobile - but the ownership of capital is typically restricted, returning the returns on capital to the owners rather than the residents or workers. Hence the reluctance of developing countries and economies in transition (the Former Soviet Union, for instance) to welcome offshore or foreign capital.
As a consequence, there are good reasons to suppose that the gains from trade are differentially distributed between the haves and the havenots, with the gains accruing largely to those that already have, despite also helping those who have not.
Meanwhile, apparent comparative advantages between countries will tend to reflect the following:
And also
ALL OF WHICH CONTRIBUTE TO COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE. [do not do unto others as you would they should do unto you - their tastes may not be the same (Shaw)] So, relativity discovered in economics (by Ricardo (1772 - 1823) as an extension of the Adam Smith logic of markets) well before Einstein did so in physics!
All of the conditions determining comparative advantage, however, (even land endowments, through land improvement - drainage, irrigation etc.)) change through time. Hence the story of the industrial revolution: UK's comparative advantage in engineering, industry etc. based on coal), food in the Colonies, then changing with "mass production" and labour intensity, with declining industries tending to be protected (that is shielded in some way from the world market), since trading conditions encourage the re-allocation of resources away from those sectors in which the country no longer has a comparative advantage.
Furthermore:
Trade Restrictions
These logics almost inevitably give rise to trade restrictions between countries, with the more common reasons for these restrictions being:
In simple terms, a countrys comparative advantage depends on its resource endowments - the more land and labour it has relative to capital, the more likely it is to have a comparative advantage in farm products. As Anderson (op. cit., p 119 - 120) remarks: since the usable capital stock per worker in those (Central and Eastern European - CEE) countries is low relative to the stock of agricultural land and other farm capital per worker, their comparative advantages during the next decade or so are likely to be in primary products and standard technology manufactures until new stocks of industrial capital accumulate (Hamilton and Winters, 1992; Anderson, 1992, 1993). He goes on: So it is in these product areas that access to EU markets is most sought after. While to date the EU has been resisting, at the behest of its domestic interest groups, there are serious concerns about immigration from, and/or political upheavals in the transforming economies should those economies not begin to prosper soon. Anderson uses the illustrative framework suggested by Leamer (1987) to summarise relative resource endowments for different countries (Figure 1).
In this Figure,
N denotes land resources (here measured as cropland); L shows population;
C indicates industrial capital (as well as other produced capital, including
skills and technology). The approximate location within this triangle of
each country (or region) can be measured relative to the world average,
which is taken as the numeraire.
Thus, the location of the world on this diagram is at point W.
Countries which lie above the line AC have relatively greater areas of
cropland per person than the world average, and are likely to have a comparative
advantage in farm products . Countries lying to the left of line NB are
relatively poor compared with the world average, implying that they also
have less capital (including human capital) to attract and earn income
per person than the world average. As an illustration, the approximate
locations of Poland (P), Hungary (H) and Germany (G) are indicated on the
diagram. From this simple and highly aggregated analysis, it seems clear
that these two CECs, at least, are likely to have a comparative advantage
in farm products (along with most of North America, South America, sub-Saharan
Africa, Australasia and much of south-eastern FSU).
The implication of this simple analysis is that liberalisation (opening up of the world economy to freer trade) should enable Poland to take advantage of its natural comparative advantage in farm products, which in turn should lead to growth of the domestic economy, especially the farm and related sectors. There is now little doubt that open economies perform better than closed economies (see, e.g. Edwards, 1993, Thomas et al., 1991, and Greenway and Sapsford, 1994). As Falvey, 1997, observes; the beneficial resource allocation effects of allowing freer trade are now widely accepted, although under the standard assumptions they appeared likely to be very small. (p2). However, he goes on: Recent developments in trade theory suggest that the resource misallocation effects may be much higher than is conventionally estimated. - The reasons have to do with the dynamic effects of trade liberalisation, where, for example, Romer, 1994, emphasises innovation and introduction of new technologies, new services, new productive activities and new types of capital and inputs, all of which tend to be stifled under more protectionist and regulated markets. In turn, such regulations and protection (and central control) encourages economic resourcefulness to be channelled towards beating (or farming) the regulations and lobbying bureaucracies (activities which are substantially unproductive, but earn rents for those who control the regulations or own the quota rights etc.) rather than on developing and growing markets (see, e.g. Feenstra, 1992) - the rent seeking phenomenon, closely associated with bribery and corruption.
[Major Refs:
A more sophsiticated economic response might well include:
Thus, we could measure the opportunity costs of the domestic resources (land, labour, and capital) used in the production of a good per unit of value added measured at border prices (the unprotected and unsupported prices), where value added is the difference between the sale price of the good and the cost per unit of the inputs used in its production. This ratio is known as the Domestic Resource Cost (DRC).
DRC = [Opportunity Costs of Resources used] divided by [Value Added produced measured at Border (unprotected) Prices]
So long as this ratio is less than one, then the production will be capable of generating a positive return over and above opportunity costs to the local or domestic resources being used - i.e. capable of generating a pure or excess profit. In a system of prefectly competitive markets, all DRCs would be equal to one - no pure or excess profit opportunities anywhere in the system. More generally, sectors with DRCs greater than one would be expected to grow (to be competitive), while those with DRCs less than one would be expected to decline (be uncompetitive) unless they can improve their productivity (or improve the value of their product by adjusting the quality to match consumers willingness to pay.
In practice, this approach is plagued by problems:
When EU prices, rather than world prices, are used as the comparitor, the competitiveness as measured by DRC generally imporves - since EU prices are generally higher than world prices, though this also applies to the prices of inputs used to generate value added.
But, does DRC measure comparative advantage? As pointed out above, in a world which fully exploits all the efficiencies of pursuing comparative advantage, specialisation and gains from trade, all DRCs would be 1 - and we would not be able to measure comparative advantages through this route. Comparative advantages would show up in such a world in trade flows, and associated balances between production, imports, exports and consumption levels in various localities, regions and countries.
But, in practice, current trade flows are distorted - competition is not the only thing driving economic activity and pursuit of profitable opportunities - governments interfere with trade and prices (for their own reasons). The effects of these interventions (and of other inefficiencies), may well be illustrated by DRCs, but these measures may NOT illustrate any underlying comparative disadvantage. For instance, suppose we measure the DRC for a sector (like cereals) in a country where support for agriculture is common place. The opportunity cost of land will be high, because of the support, as will the opportunity cost of capital (since there will be more capital used), as will the cost of labour (since there will be more people trying to earn a living from the industry than otherwise). DRCs, in this case, are quite likely to show that the sector is uncompetitive. However, if and when the support were to be removed, the employment of factors in the industry would adjust, as would the value of land, and the sector would be shown to be competitive after all.
Reference to Domestic
Resource Cost measures: Mat Gorton and Sophia Davidova, on
CEC agriculture's competitiveness and DRC Measures
Competitiveness deals with the notions of whether one product (and thus its supply or marketing chain) can compete in the market place and sustain, if not improve, its share of the total market and the total value it can add to the raw materials as the products move through the chain. Although the principle of comparative advantage still operates, the extent of competition and competitiveness involves rather more than simply how good you are at making this product compared with your ability to make other products.
The concept of the production/marketing processes used here is still very simple - it simply involves organising your resources (land, labour, capital and management) to produce products which are wanted (that is, for which people are prepared to pay good money). While it will still pay you to produce the products which you are best at, there is now more to it than that. Inclusion of the key elements of products, as opposed to commodities, suggests that competitiveness will depend on being distinctive from the competition in ways which are, and will continue to be, regarded as valuable by the user. This implies that the product (or the resources which are needed for its production) are relatively rare, otherwise the consumer or user can turn to other sources than yours. It also implies that there should be few, ideally no imitations or substitutes available, since the existence of either good imitations or substitutes for your product will reduce the amounts consumers and users are willing to pay for your product.
In shorthand, these attributes of competitive products (valuable, rare, inimitable, unsubstitutable) can be labelled as the products competitive advantage (which is obviously rather different from and more sophisticated than comparative advantage).
What is that makes firms (production/marketing systems) and their resources distinctive? Since technolgies are frequently easily copied and most resources are fairly commonly available, distinctiveness must rely on more intangible aspects of business organisation. Kay identifies four key elements to a firms (or marketing chains) distinctiveness:
Competitiveness, according to these concepts, now involves harnessing a firms distinctive capabilities to the competitive advantage of the actual and potential products (and their underlying resources), with the primary objective of adding value to the product (as a combination of inputs and resources), since it is the added value which provides the income and profit to the firm or chain. It is this combination of competitive advantage and distinctive capability which determines the competitiveness of the firm or chain.
Major Refs:
John Kay, Foundations of Corporate Success, Oxford University Press,
1993.
R.E. Westgren, Firm Resources, Industrial Organisation and Austrian
Economics: The Bases for a New Strategic Management Approach to Competitiveness,
in Agricultural Competitiveness: Market Forces and Policy Choice, Proceedings
of 22nd. Conf. International Ag. Economists, Harare, Aug, 1994, Peters,
G. and Hedley, D (eds.), Dartmouth, 1995