MONETARY UNION?
Preliminaries: The Key Issues of Macroeconomic Management: Two Key
Questions
- How fast can the economy grow?
What is a sustainable growth rate without generating inflationary
pressures?
What should the MPC assume the underlying long term growth rate of the
economy to be? If it assumes too high a rate, it will generate
inflation.
If it assumes too low a rate, monetary policy will be too tight to
allow
the economy to grow as much as possible. See above,
and also two more (oldish) articles from the Economist on:
- How Big or Small
should
the Budget Deficit be?
- Current spending by governments (as
opposed to
spending
on Capital Investment) should be balanced by taxation revenues over the
course of the economic cycle - automatic stabilisers
- Capital investment (improving the capacity
of
the economy
to generate incomes and output) can justify borrowing (government debts
and deficits)
- Total public debt (amounts owed to the
private
sector)
need to be serviced (interest has to be paid). So there is an
upper
limit on the total public debt (currently set at 40% of GDP by the UK
government)
- Leaves two major questions (to which there
are
currently
no clear answers):
- What counts as capital investment as far
as
government
spending is concerned?
- What is a sensible upper limit on Public
Debt?
In other words, how much public debt is the economy and the electorate
willing to pay for?
- These two questions are inter-related -
the
more convinced
people are that government spending is capital investment - improving
the
capacity of the economy to generate incomes, output and well-being -
the
greater will be its willingness to pay for this investment and bear the
costs of a large public debt. Furthermore, the answers to these
questions
are essentially political - they need to be answered through public
debate,
discussion and election.
-
The Essence of
Macroeconomic
Management (what you should have learned!):
- Matching the growth of the economy with
its
capacity
to sustain growth - Ye versus Yf.
- Unsustainable growth rates (Ye > Yf)
mean
overheating
and decay - inflation and (later) unemployment
- Restricted growth rates (Ye < Yf) mean
under-utilisation,
unemployment, and atrophy
- variations in interest rates, inflation
rates,
unemployment
rates and exchange rates (both over time and between different
countries
at the same time) are symptoms, not causes, of these imbalances
or different balances between yields (actual growth rates) and
capacities
(potential and sustainable) growth rates.
- Properly interpreted and properly managed,
these
symptoms
(interest rates, exchange rates, inflation rates and unemployment
rates)
are also signals - what needs to be done and what needs to change to
regain
the balance between yield and capacity
Is the Euro a Good
Thing for
the UK? What is Monetary
Union?
What are the advantages and disadvantages of a Common Currency?
What does European Monetary Union actually
mean?
In macroeconomic terms, it means:
- that what used to be international trade
(exports
and imports) and international capital movements (transactions) now
become internal or inter-regional or
inter-sectoral trades and transactions. In our Circular Flow of Income
representation of the macroeconomy - the boundaries are re-drawn the reduce
the
flows of imports and exports (which now
represent only the
trade which happen between the currency area and the rest of the world).
- there will be no exchange rate and no
forex
market
between countries in the Union.
- It also means that, instead of there being
several Monetary
Authorities (each of the countries' central banks) there is now
only
one - the European Central Bank (ECB) - so there will be a
common
monetary policy rather than a combination of somewhat separate monetary
policies, and a common interest rate in countries in the Union.
So, what does Monetary Union actually DO?
- reduces transactions costs and uncertainty
(far
fewer
exchange rate variations to worry about);
- and makes inter-regional comparisons of
costs,
prices
and wages more transparent and obvious; changes the signals of
economic
performance and competitiveness - no longer the exchange rate, but now:
differential wages, prices, costs and unemployment rates between
regions;
- changes the monetary authority and the
conduct
of monetary
policy - and almost certainly towards 'prudent' monetary policy
emphasising
stable growth in money supply at about the underlying real growth rate
of the economy to avoid inflation (unlike the history of France and,
especially,
Italy, though more like the German history).
So What?
- The Multiplier will tend to be larger within the Union than in
the
separate
countries before Union, because there are now fewer leakages out of the
Unions Circular Flow of Income. But this is really only an
accounting
change - the sums are now done over a larger area and greater number of
economic transactions than before. The multiplier for the UK will not
change
much if at all.
- The key difference is that there are fewer "buffers" between
different
rates of growth and different rates of unemployment and inflation in
different
areas of the Union:
- Prior to Monetary Union, countries could experience and sustain
different
rates of growth, inflation and unemployment because these differences
were
reconciled or buffered by differences in both:
- national interest rates
- exchange rates
- Within the Monetary Union, these buffering mechanisms are
removed
- - there is no exchange rate (or rather the exchange rate is
fixed and
immutable
at 1:1);
- there is a common interest rate established by the European
Central
Bank.
- This means that differences in regional growth rates (Ye) versus
the
capacities
of these regions to sustain these growth rates (Yf) now show up as
regional
variations in:
- price pressures and levels - higher prices and wages in rapidly
growing
and rich regions versus lower prices and wages in the slower growing
and
poorer regions (e.g price of houses, beer, etc. between the south and
north
of the UK)
- employment rates (higher in the rich and rapidly growing
regions and
lower
elsewhere)
- costs of capital (risk premia on effective interest rates -
those which
are actually paid and earned) - capital is cheaper where it is
plentiful
and more expensive where it is scarce and more risky.
- These signals should, according to the logic of markets:
- encourage growth in the slower growing regions and discourage
growth in
the rapidly growing regions
- encourage people and capital to move from the expensive regions
to the
cheaper regions.
- But, the extent to which these market signals trigger these
changes
depends
on the extent to which at least some people and some capital are
willing
and able to move between regions.
- people are more or less attached to their present locations and
more or
less comfortable with their present communities
- capital finds it easier and less risky to be close to areas of
rapid
growth
- which are characterised by good infrastructure, close networks of
related
sectors, supply chains, marketing chains, management linkages etc.
- Because people do not want to move, and capital does not want to
take
unecessary
risks
- regional differences and disparities persist in any monetary
union
(e.g.
in the UK at present, or in the US, or in the EU). e.g. the following
chart,
which shows the relative average growth rates of countries of
the
EU and regions of the US (a long standing monetary union).
-

- So, what do people do when they want to preserve their ways of
life?
They club together and form communities, and nation states.
- they form national (and regional) governments to protect
themselves
from
their neighbours and traders, who become competitors rather than
cooperators
- Monetary Union, then, is a step to removing and reducing
these
national
barriers and protective devices.
While the UK stands out here as behaving
substantially
differently from Germany, we have already seen that these countries
followed
very different monetary and exchange rate policies during at least the
early part of this period - and the effects of these differences were
to
generate different forms of economic cycle - the UK (and France and
Italy)
showing more inflation and reductions in competitiveness than Germany.
In the future, given the lessons learned from
history
and the change in the central bank's independence in the UK, one would
expect much more similar performance, even rather better in the UK in
the
medium term (as evidenced in more recent history) given currently more
flexible labour markets than in unified Germany.
Dealing with regional disparities - especially
unemployment 'black spots'
This requires fiscal policy to assist high
unemployment
areas and provide appropriate social security and labour
mobility/flexibility
programmes. Fiscal policy will still be under national control, though
heavily constrained by the Government Borrowing restrictions under the
EU Stability Pact - budget deficits no more than 3% of GDP,
National
Debt no more than 60% of GDP.
Notice - this is a Stability Pact, and not
just criteria for EMU members. It is a pact which seeks to reduce
instability between countries and resulting variations in exchange
rates.
The UK will be judged and bound by this pact whether inside or outside
the EMU itself.
There are questions about whether these
constraints
are too tight to allow countries to assist adjustment in the
'peripheral'
regions, and whether these regions will be evenly distributed within
countries
or whether some countries might be more 'peripheral' than others.
If these constraints prove too tight for
political
and economic response to uncompetitive regions and sectors, what will
happen?
It seems likely that ways round the stability pact will be found (as
they
already have been in determining the qualifiers for the initial euro
area
- not all initial members really qualify unabiguously under the
budget/national
debt criteria.)
These ways might be a larger European Union
budget
- currently restricted to 1.27% of GDP, and far too small to provide
for
significant transfers from the better off to the poorer regions. Or
they
might simply relax the stability pact. It seems (at present) unlikely
that
the euro will be allowed to break up or fall apart on this count.
Member
states will find compromises and reconciliations which will resolve
these
difficulties. In particular, common fiscal policies will not
prove to be acceptable on these grounds, if no others. Common
fiscal
policies are NOT part of the monetary union, in spite of frequent
proetstations
to the contrary.
Is it a good or a bad
thing?
You have to make up your own mind:
The Government's Five Economic Tests (see Official Euro Site
below)
"which will define whether a clear an unambiguous case can be made"
are:
G. Brown's 5 Economic Tests
|
Optimistic Answers:
|
Pessimistic Answers
|
Sustainable convergence between UK and
economies
of the single currency? |
EMU would reduce UK interest rates,
leading to more
growth,and more inflationary pressure. However, inflationary
effects
of exchange rate depreciation would be substantially reduced. And
common
monetary policy would encourage convergence once UK joins. |
UK not now prefectly synchonised with EMU
countries,
and never will be, especially since UK economy is more sensitive to
interest
rates than other countries, mainly because of the importance of home
ownership
(through mortgages) than elsewhere. In any event, convergence likely to
be slow and uncertain. |
Whether there is sufficient flexibility
to cope
with economic change? |
EMU monetary policy is as flexible as the
UKs. UK
economy at least as flexible as those of other countries, so UK would
have
a competitive advantage.
The euro is too big an enterprise to be
compromised
by imprudent management, and european fiscal policies will necessarily
evolve greater national and regional discretion rather than
harmonisation. |
Interest rates which are unsuitable for UK
economy
would more than offset any flexibility advantage. Furthermore, lack of
flexibility in Euro labour markets will undermine management of the
Euro
in favour of unemployment, and lead to generally inflationary
management
of the euro, or strong pressures for greater harmony in european fiscal
policies. |
The effect on Investment? |
ER volatility (and non EMU membership)
reduces investment,
as does higher interest rates, so investment and growth would be higher
in EMU |
Will only be positive if the economies
converge, which,
as argued above, is unlikely and not soon. |
The Impact on financial services? |
Irrelevant - no reason why this single
sector should
be singled out. In any event, no reason to suppose that it would be
significantly
disadvantaged (since it was not when UK left the ERM (fixed rate with
Euro)
in 1997). |
Joining would reduce sterling forex
markets, in which
UK has a clear competitive advantage. |
Whether membership would be good for
employment? |
Improved stability and better growth and
investment
should promote jobs. |
Lack of convergence, and inappropriate
interest rates
would reduce growth and employment. |
The critical dimensions of
the
effects of EMU membership revolve round:
- Whether a common monetary policy will fit the UKs
circumstances?
Is the UK likely to experience substantially different economic
conditions
than the other members, especially once in the system? What
reasons
can be advanced to suggest these differences?
- Will the UK respond to a common monetary policy in similar
fashion to
the
other members? The importance of the housing sector in the UK economy
relative
to some other members might suggest so, but would the housing market
adjust
to this new circumstance? Otherwise, why should the UK economy be
differently sensitive to interest rates than other economies?
The heart of the economics argument could be expressed as follows:
- Pro: The UK economy has traditionally shown considerable
BoP and
exchange rate volatility. This is especially important in times
of
recession and recovery, where interest rate reductions and stronger
growth
both tend to lead to exchange rate depreciation (BoP deficits), which
increases
import prices and might lead to an earlier onset of inflationary
expectations
than otherwise and thus to premature deflationary policy? EMU
membership
would certainly reduce UKs exchange rate volatility, and furthermore,
would
harmonise exchange rate fluctuations with those of the rest of the euro
area, tending to encourage convergence of macroeconomic conditions.
Coupled
with the arguments about reduced transactions costs, improved
competition,
and hence imporved growth and investment, the case for membership in
principle
seems strong. But, the last time we experienced a substantial recovery
phase, coupled with substantial depreciation of sterling (1992, when we
left the exchange rate mechanism) there was no substantial imported
inflation
effect, contrary to many predictions. Furthermore:
- Con: The UK economy has substantially outperformed the
eurozone
since
1993: both began this period with unemployment rates at about
10%,
but the UK showed more rapid and larger declines - to about 3% by
2000/1,
while the eurozone has shown persistent unemployment at 10% till 1998/9
and is currently experienceing unemployments rates at more than 8% and
rising, unlike the UK's which appears stable and low. Since 1991
(=100) UK real national income has increased to almost 130, while the
eurozone
stands only at 120. UK growth was only bettered by the Eurozone in one
year of these 11 most recent years - in 1992. The UK's future
prosepcts
from growth and employment look at least as good if not considerably
better
than the Eurozone's - so what is the argument which supports
change?
But, it might be pointed out, would the UK not have performed equally
well
if we had been in? After all, Ireland has managed pretty well.
And
how much of the eurozone's pooerer preformance is down to the euro
experiment?
After all, many of these economies are less flexible than the UKs,
which
would indicate slower growth and higher rates of unemployment,
and
Germany, as major player, has experienced the substantial
economic
dislocation of the unification of Germany, which would have occured
anyway.
Furthermore, the UK has had the benefit of prudent monetary policy
since
1997 (when the BoE became responsible), which has clearly contributed
substantially
to our better economic perfomance since then. This prudent
management
would not go away with euro membership, albeit over a much larger and
more
diverse economy. Back to the critical
issues
above.
The answers to all these questions involve hypothetical
conditions:
what if the UK joined the Euro: what would happen compared with what
would
happen if we remained outside? There cannot be any "clear and
unambiguous
case" - there will always be grounds for contesting the assumptions and
or the measurements and modelling of the various effects. The
Chancellor's
statement, then, could be interpreted as a statement that we will never
join - since there can never be a clear an unabiguous case. This
argument has been made, in an interesting and insightful way, by
Stephen
King (Managing Director of Economics, HSBC) from the standpoint of
some time in the future (after we joined) as to whether we should stay
in or not. He argued (in an old Independent
article, which I have now lost!) that the same five tests could equally
well be used, in the future, to decide if we should leave EMU,
presuming that we had decided to join at sometime in the past.
"The tests are eerily familiar. Didn't we have
something
like this in 2002?" says a Treasury mandarin. - these tests are
not unambiguously applicable - they can never provide a certain or
positive result.
See here for more thoughts and links on this key question.
But this decision is far too important to be left to uninformed
debate
and "knee-jerk" reactions. It needs careful thought and
consideration.
I hope this course has provided some major parts of the basis for such
careful thought and consideration.
Footnote: These points
all deal with the effect of EMU membership on economic growth, as
measured by GDP. However, as pointed out elsewhere in these
notes, GDP may not measure social
progress very well. The New Economics
Foundation has published (2004) a new adjustment of UK GDP to reflect
the
costs of progress - crime, resource depletion, pollution and climate
change etc. - to produce a Measure of Domestic
Progress (MDP). Would
Europe be better placed to deal with these issues if the UK were inside
the EMU or not? Open question. Is the UK better placed to
influence, and be influenced by our European partners by joining the
EMU or not? And, if so, would this be a good thing?
Back to ACE8015 Index.